Auction

"Auctioneer" redirects here. For the DC Comics supervillain, see Auctioneer (comics).
An auctioneer and her assistants scan the crowd for bidders.
An American auctioneer at a livestock auction, November 2010

An auction is a process of buying and selling goods or services by offering them up for bid, taking bids, and then selling the item to the highest bidder. The open ascending price auction is arguably the most common form of auction in use today.[1] Participants bid openly against one another, with each subsequent bid required to be higher than the previous bid.[2] An auctioneer may announce prices, bidders may call out their bids themselves (or have a proxy call out a bid on their behalf), or bids may be submitted electronically with the highest current bid publicly displayed.[2] In a Dutch auction, the auctioneer begins with a high asking price for some quantity of like items; the price is lowered until a participant is willing to accept the auctioneer's price for some quantity of the goods in the lot or until the seller's reserve price is met.[2] While auctions are most associated in the public imagination with the sale of antiques, paintings, rare collectibles and expensive wines, auctions are also used for commodities, livestock, radio spectrum and used cars. In economic theory, an auction may refer to any mechanism or set of trading rules for exchange.

History

Artemis, Ancient Greek marble sculpture. In 2007, a Roman-era bronze sculpture of "Artemis and the Stag" was sold at Sotheby's in New York for US$28.6 million, by far exceeding its estimates and at the time setting the new record as the most expensive sculpture as well as work from antiquity ever sold at auction.[3][4]

The word "auction" is derived from the Latin augeō which means "I increase" or "I augment".[1] For most of history, auctions have been a relatively uncommon way to negotiate the exchange of goods and commodities. In practice, both haggling and sale by set-price have been significantly more common.[5] Indeed, before the seventeenth century the few auctions that were held were sporadic.[6]

Nonetheless, auctions have a long history, having been recorded as early as 500 B.C.[7] According to Herodotus, in Babylon auctions of women for marriage were held annually. The auctions began with the woman the auctioneer considered to be the most beautiful and progressed to the least. It was considered illegal to allow a daughter to be sold outside of the auction method.[6]

During the Roman Empire, following military victory, Roman soldiers would often drive a spear into the ground around which the spoils of war were left, to be auctioned off. Later slaves, often captured as the "spoils of war", were auctioned in the forum under the sign of the spear, with the proceeds of sale going towards the war effort.[6]

The Romans also used auctions to liquidate the assets of debtors whose property had been confiscated.[8] For example, Marcus Aurelius sold household furniture to pay off debts, the sales lasting for months.[9] One of the most significant historical auctions occurred in the year 193 A.D. when the entire Roman Empire was put on the auction block by the Praetorian Guard. On March 23 The Praetorian Guard first killed emperor Pertinax, then offered the empire to the highest bidder. Didius Julianus outbid everyone else for the price of 6,250 drachmas per guard, an act that initiated a brief civil war. Didius was then beheaded two months later when Septimius Severus conquered Rome.[8]

From the end of the Roman Empire to the eighteenth century auctions lost favor in Europe,[8] while they had never been widespread in Asia.[6]

Modern revival

A Peep at Christies (1796) - caricature of actress Elizabeth Farren and huntsman Lord Derby examining paintings at Christie's, by James Gillray.

In some parts of England during the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries auction by candle began to be used for the sale of goods and leaseholds.[10] In a candle auction, the end of the auction was signaled by the expiration of a candle flame, which was intended to ensure that no one could know exactly when the auction would end and make a last-second bid. Sometimes, other unpredictable processes, such as a footrace, were used in place of the expiration of a candle. This type of auction was first mentioned in 1641 in the records of the House of Lords.[11] The practice rapidly became popular, and in 1660 Samuel Pepys's diary recorded two occasions when the Admiralty sold surplus ships "by an inch of candle". Pepys also relates a hint from a highly successful bidder, who had observed that, just before expiring, a candle-wick always flares up slightly: on seeing this, he would shout his final - and winning - bid. The London Gazette began reporting on the auctioning of artwork at the coffeehouses and taverns of London in the late 17th century.

The Microcosm of London (1808), an engraving of Christie's auction room.

The first known auction house in the world was Stockholm Auction House, Sweden (Stockholms Auktionsverk), founded by Baron Claes Rålamb in 1674.[12][13] Sotheby's, currently the world's second-largest auction house,[12] was founded in London on 11 March 1744, when Samuel Baker presided over the disposal of "several hundred scarce and valuable" books from the library of an acquaintance. Christie's, now the world's largest auction house,[12] was founded by James Christie in 1766 in London[14] and published its first auction catalog in 1766, although newspaper advertisements of Christie's sales dating from 1759 have been found.[15]

Other early auction houses that are still in operation include Dorotheum (1707), Mallams (1788), Bonhams (1793), Phillips de Pury & Company (1796), Freeman's (1805) and Lyon & Turnbull (1826).[16]

By the end of the 18th century, auctions of art works were commonly held in taverns and coffeehouses. These auctions were held daily, and auction catalogs were printed to announce available items. In some cases these catalogs were elaborate works of art themselves, containing considerable detail about the items being auctioned. At this time, Christie's established a reputation as a leading auction house, taking advantage of London's status as the major centre of the international art trade after the French Revolution.

During the American civil war goods seized by armies were sold at auction by the Colonel of the division. Thus, some of today's auctioneers in the U.S. carry the unofficial title of "colonel".[9]

The development of the internet, however, has led to a significant rise in the use of auctions as auctioneers can solicit bids via the internet from a wide range of buyers in a much wider range of commodities than was previously practical.[5]

In 2008, the National Auctioneers Association reported that the gross revenue of the auction industry for that year was approximately $268.4 billion, with the fastest growing sectors being agricultural, machinery, and equipment auctions and residential real estate auctions.

Types

Primary

Tuna auction at the Tsukiji fish market in Tokyo
Fish auction in Honolulu, Hawaii

Secondary

Genres

The range of auctions that take place is extremely wide and you can buy almost anything, from a house to an endowment policy and everything in-between. Indeed, some of the more interesting recent developments have been the use of the Internet both as a means of disseminating information about various auctions and as a vehicle for hosting auctions themselves.

Here's a short description of the most common types of auction.

A bidder could find themselves bidding for items which are still plugged in, and the great advantage of these auctions taking place on the premises is that they have the opportunity to view the goods as they were being used, and may be able to try them out. Bidders can also avoid the possibility of goods being damaged whilst they are being removed as they can do it or at least supervise the activity.

Time requirements

Each type of auction has its specific qualities such as pricing accuracy and time required for preparing and conducting the auction. The number of simultaneous bidders is of critical importance. Open bidding during an extended period of time with many bidders will result in a final bid that is very close to the true market value. Where there are few bidders and each bidder is allowed only one bid, time is saved, but the winning bid may not reflect the true market value with any degree of accuracy. Of special interest and importance during the actual auction is the time elapsed from the moment that the first bid is revealed to the moment that the final (winning) bid has become a binding agreement.

Characteristics

Auctions can differ in the number of participants:

Prices are bid by buyers and asked (or offered) by sellers. Auctions may also differ by the procedure for bidding (or asking, as the case may be):

Auctions may differ as to the price at which the item is sold, whether the first (best) price, the second price, the first unique price or some other. Auctions may set a reservation price which is the least/maximum acceptable price for which a good may be sold/bought.

Without modification, auction generally refers to an open, demand auction, with or without a reservation price (or reserve), with the item sold to the highest bidder.

Supply auction
Demand auction
Double auction

Common uses

Auctions are publicly and privately seen in several contexts and almost anything can be sold at auction. Some typical auction arenas include the following:

Farm clearing sale, Woolbrook, NSW.
Grass-fed cattle at auction, Walcha, NSW.
Wool buyers' room at a wool auction, Newcastle, NSW.

Although less publicly visible, the most economically important auctions are the commodities auctions in which the bidders are businesses even up to corporation level. Examples of this type of auction include:

Bidding strategy

An 18th century Chinese meiping porcelain vase. Porcelain has long been a staple at art sales. In 2005, a 14th-century Chinese porcelain piece was sold by the Christie's for £16 million, or US$28 million. It set a world auction record for any ceramic work of art.[55]

Katehakis and Puranam provided the first model[56] for the problem of optimal bidding for a firm that in each period procures items to meet a random demand by participating in a finite sequence of auctions. In this model an item valuation derives from the sale of the acquired items via their demand distribution, sale price, acquisition cost, salvage value and lost sales. They established monotonicity properties for the value function and the optimal dynamic bid policy. They also provided a model[57] for the case in which the buyer must acquire a fixed number of items either at a fixed buy-it-now price in the open market or by participating in a sequence of auctions. The objective of the buyer is to minimize his expected total cost for acquiring the fixed number of items.

Bid shading

Bid shading is placing a bid which is below the bidder's actual value for the item. Such a strategy risks losing the auction, but has the possibility of winning at a low price. Bid shading can also be a strategy to avoid the Winner's curse.

Chandelier or rafter bidding

This is the practice, especially by high-end art auctioneers, of raising false bids at crucial times in the bidding in order to create the appearance of greater demand or to extend bidding momentum for a work on offer. To call out these nonexistent bids auctioneers might fix their gaze at a point in the auction room that is difficult for the audience to pin down.

In the United Kingdom this practice is legal on property auctions up to but not including the reserve price, and is also known as off-the-wall bidding.[58]

Collusion

Whenever bidders at an auction are aware of the identity of the other bidders there is a risk that they will form a "ring" and thus manipulate the auction result, a practice known as collusion. By agreeing to bid only against outsiders, never against members of the "ring", competition becomes weaker, which may dramatically affect the final price level. After the end of the official auction an unofficial auction may take place among the "ring" members. The difference in price between the two auctions could then be split among the members. This form of a ring was used as a central plot device in the opening episode of the 1979 British television series The House of Caradus, 'For Love or Money', uncovered by Helena Caradus on her return from Paris.

A ring can also be used to increase the price of an auction lot, in which the owner of the object being auctioned may increase competition by taking part in the bidding him or herself, but drop out of the bidding just before the final bid. In Britain and many other countries, rings and other forms of bidding on one's own object are illegal. This form of a ring was used as a central plot device in an episode of the British television series Lovejoy (series 4, episode 3), in which the price of a watercolour by the (fictional) Jessie Webb is inflated so that others by the same artist could be sold for more than their purchase price.

In an English auction, a dummy bid is a bid made by a dummy bidder acting in collusion with the auctioneer or vendor, designed to deceive genuine bidders into paying more. In a first-price auction, a dummy bid is an unfavourable bid designed so as not to become the winning bid. (The bidder does not want to win this auction, but he or she wants to make sure to be invited to the next auction).

In Australia, a dummy bid (shill, schill) is a criminal offence, but a vendor bid or a co-owner bid below the reserve price is permitted, if clearly declared as such by the auctioneer. These are all official legal terms in Australia, but may have other meanings elsewhere. A co-owner is one of two or several owners (who disagree among themselves).

In Sweden and many other countries there are no legal restrictions, but it will severely hurt the reputation of an auction house that knowingly permits any other bids except genuine bids. If the reserve is not reached this should be clearly declared.

In South Africa auctioneers can use their staff or any bidder to raise the price as long as its disclosed before the auction sale. The Auction Alliance[59] controversy focused on vendor bidding and it was proven to be legal and acceptable in terms of the South African consumer laws.

Suggested opening bid (SOB)

There will usually be an estimate of what price the lot will fetch. In an ascending open auction it is considered important to get at least a 50-percent increase in the bids from start to finish. To accomplish this, the auctioneer must start the auction by announcing a suggested opening bid (SOB) that is low enough to be immediately accepted by one of the bidders. Once there is an opening bid, there will quickly be several other, higher bids submitted. Experienced auctioneers will often select an SOB that is about 45 percent of the (lowest) estimate. Thus there is a certain margin of safety to ensure that there will indeed be a lively auction with many bids submitted. Several observations indicate that the lower the SOB, the higher the final winning bid. This is due to the increase in the number of bidders attracted by the low SOB.

A chi-squared distribution shows many low bids but few high bids. Bids "show up together"; without several low bids there will not be any high bids.

Another approach to choosing an SOB: The auctioneer may achieve good success by asking the expected final sales price for the item, as this method suggests to the potential buyers the item's particular value. For instance, say an auctioneer is about to sell a $1,000 car at a sale. Instead of asking $100, hoping to entice wide interest (for who wouldn't want a $1,000 car for $100?), the auctioneer may suggest an opening bid of $1,000; although the first bidder may begin bidding at a mere $100, the final bid may more likely approach $1,000.

Terminology

Duo Yun Xuan auction house in Malacca, Malaysia.

JEL classification

The Journal of Economic Literature (JEL) classification code for auctions is D44.[65]

See also

Notes

  1. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Krishna, 2002: p2
  2. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 McAfee, Dinesh Satam; McMillan, Dinesh (1987), "Auctions and Bidding" (PDF), Journal of Economic Literature (American Economic Association, published June 1987) 25 (2), pp. 699–738, JSTOR 2726107, retrieved 2008-06-25
  3. Sotheby's (2007-06-07), Sotheby's Sets a New World Record for Sculpture at Auction (PDF), retrieved 2008-06-20
  4. New York Times (2008-01-10), "Artemis and Stag at Met Museum", The New York Times, retrieved 2008-06-20
  5. 1 2 "The Heyday of the Auction", The Economist 352 (8129), 1999-07-24: 67–68, ISSN 0013-0613
  6. 1 2 3 4 Shubik, 2004: p214
  7. Krishna, 2002: p1
  8. 1 2 3 Shubik, 2004: p215
  9. 1 2 Doyle, Robert A.; Baska, Steve (November 2002), "History of Auctions: From ancient Rome to today's high-tech auctions", Auctioneer, archived from the original on 2014-06-02, retrieved 2008-06-22
  10. R.W. Patten. "Tatworth Candle Auction." Folklore 81, No. 2 (Summer 1970), 132-135
  11. William S. Walsh A Handy Book Of Curious Information Comprising Strange Happenings in the Life of Men and Animals, Odd Statistics, Extraordinary Phenomena and Out of the Way Facts Concerning the Wonderlands of the Earth. Philadelphia: J.B. Lippincott Co., 1913. 63-64.
  12. 1 2 3 Varoli, John (2007-10-02), "Swedish Auction House to Sell 8 Million Euros of Russian Art", Bloomberg.com News (Moscow: Bloomberg Finance L.P.), retrieved 2008-06-21
  13. About the company, Stockholm, Sweden: Stockholms Auktionsverk, archived from the original on May 22, 2008, retrieved 2008-06-21
  14. "Christies.com – About Us". Retrieved 3 December 2008. James Christie conducted the first sale in London on 5 December 1766.
  15. Gazetteer and London Daily Advertiser (London, England), Saturday, 25 September 1762; Issue 10460
  16. Stoica, Michael (August 2007), The Business of Art, retrieved 2008-06-21
  17. eBay, Selling Multiple Items in a Listing (Dutch Auction), retrieved 2009-01-09
  18. Shor, Mikhael, "blind auction" Dictionary of Game Theory Terms
  19. Krishna, 2002: p13
  20. Krishna, 2002: p9
  21. Krishna, 2002: p3
  22. Milgrom, 2004: p119
  23. Nasri, Grace (2011-04-07). "The Seduction of the Penny Auction". Huffington Post. Retrieved 2011-04-27.
  24. "QuiBids.com Reviews – Legit or Scam?". Reviewopedia.com. Retrieved 13 November 2012.
  25. 1 2 3 4 5 6 Gallien, Jérémie; Gupta, Shobhit (May 2007), "Temporary and Permanent Buyout Prices in Online Auctions", Management Science (INFORMS) 53 (5): 814–833, doi:10.1287/mnsc.1060.0650, ISSN 1526-5501
  26. 1 2 Pekec, Aleksandar; Rothkopf, Michael H. (November 2003), "Combinatorial auction design", Management Science (INFORMS) 49 (11): 1485–1503, doi:10.1287/mnsc.49.11.1485.20585, ISSN 1526-5501 Check date values in: |year= / |date= mismatch (help)
  27. "Auction Types & Terms". Auctusdev.com. Retrieved 2012-12-26.
  28. https://wayback.archive.org/web/*/http://www.lloyds.com/Lloyds_Market/Capacity/Capacity_auctions/Auction_process.htm
  29. Ralph Brody, Marcie Goodman, Fund-raising events: strategies and programs for success, Human Sciences Press, 1988, ISBN 0898853621
  30. Harold W. Donahue, The Toastmaster's Manual, Kessinger Publishing, 2005, ISBN 1419156365
  31. Julia L. Wilkinson, The Ebay Price Guide: What Sells for What, No Starch Press, 2006, ISBN 1593270550
  32. 1 2 3 Fisher, Steven (2006), The Real Estate Investor's Handbook: The Complete Guide for the Individual Investor, Ocala, Florida: Atlantic Publishing Company, pp. 89–90, ISBN 0-910627-69-X
  33. 1 2 3 4 Good, Steven L.; Lynn, Paul A. (January 2007), "The eBay Effect", Commercial Investment Real Estate (CCIM Institute), retrieved 2009-06-25
  34. Leichman, Laurence (1996), 90% off! real estate, Ocala, Florida: Leichman Assoc Pubns, pp. 78–79, ISBN 0-9636867-7-1
  35. Schoenherr, Tobias; Mabert, Vincent A. (September–October 2007), "Online reverse auctions: Common myths versus evolving reality", Business Horizons (Kelley School of Business, Indiana University) 50 (5): 373–384, doi:10.1016/j.bushor.2007.03.003
  36. Moshe, Shalev; Stee, Asbjornsen (Fall 2010). "Electronic reverse auctions and the public sector - factors of success". J. Public Procurement 10 (3): 428–452. Retrieved 19 January 2014.
  37. "Free Online Reverse Auctions". Oltiby.com. Retrieved 2012-12-26.
  38. Ab Hugh, Dafydd. A Balance of Power. Star Trek Press, 1995
  39. 1 2 3 4 5 Isaac, R. Mark; Schnier, Kurt (October 2005), "Silent auctions in the field and in the laboratory", Economic Inquiry (Oxford, United Kingdom: Western Economic Association International) 43 (4): 715–733, doi:10.1093/ei/cbi050, ISSN 0095-2583
  40. Milgrom, 2004: p268
  41. 1 2 Milgrom, 2004: p267
  42. Milgrom, 2004: pp. 267-268
  43. Peter, Cramton (2006), "Simultaneous Ascending Auctions", in Cramton, Peter; Shoham, Yoav; Steinberg, Richard, Combinatorial Auctions, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, ISBN 978-0-262-03342-8
  44. http://www.ssc.wisc.edu/~dquint/econ805%202007/econ%20805%20lecture%2012.pdf
  45. Wikiversity:Economic Classroom Experiments/Private Value Auctions
  46. "Government Auctions". http://governmentauctionsuk.com. External link in |website= (help);
  47. "Police Auctions". http://policeauctionsuk.co.uk/. External link in |website= (help);
  48. Canadian Museum of Civilization and Canada Postal Museum – Auction of Fine Art and Stamps
  49. The Land Newspaper, Prime sheep, Rural Press, 13 August 2009.
  50. Combined factors hit wool auctions hard
  51. William Inglis & Son Limited
  52. d'Arcy, Susan (2010-01-24). "Bag a holiday bargain in an online auction". The Times (London).
  53. Pickles Auctions
  54. Gray, T. W. (2005). Local-based, alternative-marketing strategy could help save more small farms. Rural Cooperatives, 72: 20–3.
  55. Melikian, Souren (2005-07-26), Chinese Jar Sets Record for Asian Art, The New York Times, retrieved 2008-06-19
  56. Katehakis, Michael; Puranam, Kartikeya S. (July 2012), "On optimal bidding in sequential procurement auctions", Operations Research Letters (INFORMS) 40 (4): 244–249, doi:10.1016/j.orl.2012.03.012
  57. Katehakis, Michael; Puranam, Kartikeya S. (October 2012), "On bidding for a fixed number of items in a sequence of auctions", European Journal of Operational Research (ELSEVIER) 222 (1): 76–84, doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2012.03.050
  58. Name:. "What is bidding off the wall? | UK Property Auctions". Ukauctions.org.uk. Retrieved 2012-12-26.
  59. Rael Levitt
  60. "Wine Valuation, Price Guides, Auction results Australia". Wickman's Fine Wine Auctions.
  61. Adam, M.T.P.; Krämer, J.; Jähnig, C.; Seifert, S.; Weinhardt, C. (2011). "Understanding auction fever: A framework for emotional bidding". Electronic Markets 21 (3): 197–207. doi:10.1007/s12525-011-0068-9.
  62. Adam, M.T.P.; Krämer, J.; Müller, M. (2015). "Auction fever! How time pressure and social competition affect bidders arousal and bids in retail auctions". Journal of Retailing 91 (3): 468–485. doi:10.1016/j.jretai.2015.01.003.
  63. "Auction Jargon, Decoded: Basic Auction Terminology". Dakil.com. Dakil Auctioneers. Feb 28, 2014.
  64. 1 2 "Auction Jargon, Decoded: Basic Auction Terminology". Feb 28, 2014.
  65. Journal of Economic Literature Classification System, American Economic Association, retrieved 2008-06-25 (D: Microeconomics, D4: Market Structure and Pricing, D44: Auctions)

References

Wikimedia Commons has media related to Auctions.

Further reading

This article is issued from Wikipedia - version of the Thursday, February 11, 2016. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike but additional terms may apply for the media files.