Catch share
Catch share is a term used to describe a fishery management system that allocates a secure privilege to harvest a specific area or percentage of a fishery’s total catch to individuals, communities or associations.[1] Types of programs that are considered catch shares include, but are not limited to, individual transferable quota (ITQs), individual fishing quota (IFQs), territorial use rights for fishing (TURFs), limited access privileges (LAPs), sectors (also known as cooperatives), and dedicated access privileges (DAPs). Catch shares provide long-term secure privileges to participants, which has been theorized as providing an incentive for efficient, sustainable use of fish stocks.[2] Actual outcomes in terms of efficiency and ecological sustainability are varied based on design and implementation of the program.
Catch share programs generally fall into two categories. Quota-based programs (e.g., ITQs) establish a fishery-wide catch limit, assign portions (or shares) of the catch to participants and hold participants directly accountable to stay within the catch limit. Area-based programs (e.g., TURFs) allocate a secure, exclusive area to participants and include appropriate controls on fishing mortality that ensure long-term sustainability of the stock. A combination of quota- and area-based approaches has also been used.
Background
The term “catch share” has taken root recently, but similar management systems providing secure and exclusive access to fishery resources have been in use for many years. Community-based management in Japan's near shore fisheries dates back to feudal times,[3] while modern individually-allocated catch share programs were first implemented by the state of Wisconsin in the early 1970s for important fish stocks in the Great Lakes.[4] Additionally, Iceland and the Netherlands implemented catch shares for important stocks in the late 1970s.[5]
The use of catch share programs worldwide has been expanding since the earliest implementations in the 1970s.[6] Some countries, such as Iceland, New Zealand and Australia, have made catch share programs the default management system. The United States has implemented the vast majority of its catch share programs in the 21st century. In 2010, catch shares were implemented in the United States Northeast Multispecies fishery and in the United States Atlantic Sea Scallop fishery.[7] In 2011, a catch share program was implemented in the Pacific Coast Groundfish Limited Entry Trawl fishery, which includes fishermen from the states of Washington, Oregon, and California.[8]
Worldwide there are nearly 200 catch share programs used in 40 countries to manage a wide variety of marine and freshwater species including finfish, sharks and crustaceans.[8] Catch shares are used in developing and industrialized nations; artisanal and industrial fleets; and in high and low value fisheries.[9]
Theory
Fisheries have historically been treated as a common property resource. The dangers of managing fisheries as a common property resource were included in the development of modern theory of fishery economics, first introduced in 1954 by H. Scott Gordon. The theoretical framework showed that the common property nature of fisheries results in competition between individual operators to increase their share of the catch, which can ultimately lead to excessive capital, such as fishing vessels and gear, overfishing and resource wastage.[10] In common property fisheries, individual operators face an incentive to harvest as many fish as quickly as possible in order to preempt the activities by other operators.[10]
Catch shares have been proposed as a potential solution for the common property challenges found in many fisheries, and have typically been implemented after a variety of other approaches have failed. Most commercial fisheries begin under open access conditions, in which any fisherman is able to enter the fishery, put in effort, and catch fish. However, if fish biomass is no longer able to sustain the amount of fishing effort exerted in the fishery, populations begin to decline and fishing becomes less profitable.[11] Conventional management systems tend to respond using “input controls” such as limiting the number of entrants to the fishery, restricting boat and gear capacity, limiting the number of days at sea, and applying catch allowances per trip. However, studies show that these approaches are sometimes ineffective in controlling overall harvest, and therefore managers often implement additional effort-based regulations, known as “output controls”, that set strict fishery catch limits.[2][12] Although catch limits have proven sufficient to sustain a fishery, these management approaches alone do not fundamentally eliminate the incentive for fishermen to compete and increase their share of the catch, which can lead to reduced fishery profitability,[13] and dangerous fishing conditions.[14]
By providing secure shares of quota to fishermen, individuals or groups, it is argued that catch share programs have the potential to fundamentally shift the behavior of fishery participants and provide incentives for long term stewardship.[6] For example, with quota-based catch shares, the value of the share is directly tied to the landings value of the fishery, which may increase if the health of the fishery improves.[15]
Many, but not all catch share programs allow for voluntary trading, a process that allows operators to purchase shares either temporarily or permanently from those willing to sell or lease shares.[16] Transfers are considered an important component of catch shares because they can promote the most economically efficient use of the resource.[17]
Outcomes
Empirical research in the past two decades has shown that catch share management of fisheries has a variety of ecological, economic and social outcomes when compared with traditional management of fishery inputs. Studies examining the ecological impacts of catch share management show that they stabilize landings and catch limits.[18] Additional research has also shown reduced discards in catch share fisheries.[18][19] However, when compared to fisheries managed under conventional catch limits, recent studies have demonstrated that catch share offer no advantages towards the long term sustainability of a fishery and may exacerbate localized fishery depletion.[18][20][21][22]
The economic impacts of catch shares are also well documented, and vary based on program design and fishery goals. Catch share programs has been shown to stop the race for fish often experienced in traditionally managed fisheries.[18] With improved certainty, catch shares have also extended season lengths, providing operators with a longer time period to harvest and the ability to coordinate fishing trips based on market conditions. Empirical evidence has shown that fisheries become more profitable as costs of fishing are reduced and dockside prices for products increase.[13][17]
Many catch share programs are designed to reduce overcapitalization, result in a reduction in active fishing vessels and a transition from many temporary fishing jobs to fewer, but more stable full-time jobs.[23]
Criticism
Changes resulting from a transition to catch shares often improve the economics of the active participants in the fishery, but in some cases are considered undesirable from a community or welfare economics perspective. In specific programs, critiques largely focus on tradeoffs which commonly involve changes in fleet capacity, employment, and aggregation of shares in the fishery.[24][25][26][27]
Reduction in fleet capacity is frequently cited as a negative outcome of catch shares, although such a reduction may be listed as explicit fishery goal.[28] Catch share fisheries can result in greater capitalization of the fishing fleet when accounting for capital required to purchase shares.[29] At the same time, catch share programs may experience a change in the structure of employment, transforming from many part-time jobs paid as a share of landings value, to fewer full-time positions paid by wages.[23][28] As a result of capacity reduction and employment shifts, programs can result in a reduction in the number of fishery participants.[28] For example, the Bering Sea crab catch share program in the United States experienced a significant reduction in the number of participants and part-time jobs and is currently operated by fewer full-time positions.[30] Although fishing jobs are longer due to the lengthening of the fishing season, the percent of total landings value paid to employees in this fishery has decreased substantially.[28] As a result, it is argued that the tradeoffs associated with certain catch share programs include increased unemployment, economic contraction of coastal communities, and economic losses to businesses and communities that rely on the fishing fleet.[31][32][33]
Although a number of catch share programs do include financing options for small businesses and new entrants, some fishing communities, academics, journalists, and non-profit organizations have claimed that catch shares serve as a mechanism for the consolidation of fishing rights, often by corporations with better financing capacity than independent fishermen.[24][29][33][34][35][36] New institutions are being developed to improve communities’ access to shares, allow new entrants into the fishery, and/or keep quota within the community. These include the development and use of permit banks, community license banks and Community Fishing Associations. Program design features, including concentration caps, owner-on-board regulations, and trading restrictions, can be used to help alleviate potential unwanted social outcomes. However, it is argued these measures have only served to mitigate, but not prevent the undesirable social and economic outcomes that accompany catch share programs.[34][37] Critics have claimed that proliferation of catch share management is reflective of the increasingly strong link between the government and the private sector, and that these programs are typically the result of special interest influence over legislation.[33]
See also
References
- ↑ "NOAA Catch Share Policy" (PDF). National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration. 2010.
- 1 2 Beddington, J.; Agnew, D.; Clark, C. (June 22, 2007). "Current Problems in the Management of Marine Fisheries". Science 316 (5832): 1713–1716. doi:10.1126/science.1137362. PMID 17588923.
- ↑ Uchida, H.; Makino, M. (2008). "The Japanese Coastal Fishery Co-management: An Overview". Case Studies in Fisheries Self-governance. Retrieved November 2010.
- ↑ Anderson, T.; Leal, D. (1993). "Fishing for Property Rights to Fish". Taking the Environment Seriously. Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc.
- ↑ Arnason, R. (2007). "Advances in Property Rights Based Fisheries Management: An Introduction" (PDF). Marine Resource Economics 22: 335–346.
- 1 2 Costello, C.; Gaines, Steven D.; Lynham, J. (September 19, 2008). "Can Catch Shares Prevent Fisheries Collapse?". Science 321 (5896): 1678–1681. doi:10.1126/science.1159478. PMID 18801999. Retrieved November 2010.
- ↑ "Catch Share Spotlight No. 16: Northeast Multispecies Sectors" (PDF). National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration. 2010.
- 1 2 Environmental Defense Fund (2008). Catch Share Fisheries and Resources: Searchable Database. Retrieved from http://apps.edf.org/page.cfm?tagID=57622
- ↑ Bonzon, K.; McIlwain, K.; Strauss, C. K.; Van Leuvan, T. (2010). Catch Shares Design Manual: A Guide for Managers and Fishermen. Environmental Defense Fund.
- 1 2 Gordon, H. S. (1954). "The Economic Theory of a Common-Property Resource: The Fishery". Bulletin of Mathematical Biology 53 (1/2): 231–252. doi:10.1007/bf02464431.
- ↑ Greboval, D. (Ed.) (1999). Managing fishing capacity: selected papers on underlying concepts and issues. FAO Fisheries Technical Paper 286. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations.
- ↑ Hilborn, J. M., Orensanz, J. M. (Lobo) and Parma. A. M. (2005). Institutions, incentives, and the future of fisheries. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Societies. (360): 47-57
- 1 2 Grafton, R. Q.; Squires, Dale; Fox, Kevin J. (2000). "Private Property and Economic Efficiency: A Study of a Common-Pool Resource". The Journal of Law and Economics 43 (2): 679–714. doi:10.1086/467469.
- ↑ Knapp, G. (2006). Effects of IFQ management on fishing safety: survey responses of Alaska halibut fishermen. ComFish Alaska, 2006.
- ↑ Newell, R. G., Sanchirico, J. N. and Kerr, S. (2002). Fishing Quota Markets. Discussion Paper 2-20. Resources for the Future. Washington, D.C.
- ↑ Grafton, R. Q. (1996). "ITQs: Theory and Practice" 6. Reviews in Fish Biology and Fisheries: 5–20.
- 1 2 Newell, R. G.; Sanchirico, J. N.; Kerr, S. (2005). "Fishing quota markets" 49 (3). Journal of Environmental Economics and Management: 437–462.
- 1 2 3 4 Essington, T. E. (2010). "Ecological indicators display reduced variation in North American catch share fisheries" (PDF). Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 107 (2): 754–759. doi:10.1073/pnas.0907252107.
- ↑ Branch, T. A. (2008). "How do individual transferable quotas affect marine ecosystems?". Fish and Fisheries 9: 1–19.
- ↑ Essington, T. E. et al. (2012). Catch shares, fisheries, and ecological stewardship: a comparative analysis of resource responses to a rights-based policy instrument. Conservation Letters. 3(5): 186-195.
- ↑ Emery, T.J.; Green, B.S.; Gardner, C.; Tisdell, J. (2012). "Are input controls required in individual transferable quota fisheries to address ecosystem based fisheries management objectives?". Marine Policy 36: 122–131. doi:10.1016/j.marpol.2011.04.005.
- ↑ Walden,, J.B.; Kirkley, J.E.; Färe, R.; Logan, P. (2012). "Productivity change under an Individual Transferable Quota management system". American Journal of Agricultural Economics 94.
- 1 2 McCay, B. J. (1995). "Social and Ecological Implications of ITQs: An Overview". Oceans and Coastal Management 28 (1–3): 3–22. doi:10.1016/0964-5691(96)00002-6.
- 1 2 Eythórsson, Einar (November 2000). "A decade of ITQ-management in Icelandic fisheries: consolidation without consensus". Marine Policy 24 (6).
- ↑ Buck, Eugene H. (September 25, 1995). "Individual Transferable Quotas in Fishery Management" (PDF). Congressional Research Service reports.
- ↑ Yandle, Tracy; Christopher Dewees (2008). "Consolidation in Individual Transferable Quota Regime: Lessons from New Zealand 1986–1999". Environmental Management 41: 915–928. doi:10.1007/s00267-008-9081-y.
- ↑ McCay, Bonnie J. (1995). "Social and Ecological Implication of ITQ's: an Overview". Ocean and Coastal Management 28.
- 1 2 3 4 Abbott, Joshua K. (2010). "Employment and Remuneration Effects of IFQs in the Bering Sea/Aleutian Islands Crab Fisheries". Marine Resource Economics 25.
- 1 2 "A cautionary tale about ITQ fisheries". Ecotrust Canada. 2009. Retrieved 6 May 2014.
- ↑ "Leasing practices in North Pacific fisheries Bering Sea and Aleutian Island crab fisheries". North Pacific Fishery Management Council. June 2009.
- ↑ Copes, Parzival. "Social Impacts of Fisheries Management Regimes Based on Individual Quota".
- ↑ Pinkerton, Evelyn (2009). "The Elephant in the Room: The Hidden Costs of ITQ Leasing". Marine Policy.
- 1 2 3 Phillips, Gregory (2002). "Private property and public interest in fisheries management: the Tasmanian rock lobster fishery". Marine Policy 26.
- 1 2 Bromley, Daniel (2009). "Abdicating Responsibility: The Deceits of Fishery Policy". Fisheries 34.
- ↑ "System turns US fishing rights into commodity, squeezes small fishermen".
- ↑ "Catch shares help corporations more than fish populations".
- ↑ "Catch shares: Consolidation and the tipping point".
Further reading
- Environmental Defense Fund (2010). "Catch Share Design Center" Catch Share Database, Directory of Resources and Game.