Edward C. Prescott
Edward C. Prescott | |
---|---|
Prescott in 2015 | |
Born |
Glens Falls, New York, USA | December 26, 1940
Nationality | United States |
Institution |
Australian National University (ANU) Arizona State University Carnegie Mellon University Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Northwestern University University of Minnesota University of Pennsylvania University of California, Santa Barbara University of Chicago New York University |
School or tradition | New classical economics |
Alma mater |
Swarthmore College Case Western Reserve University Carnegie Mellon University |
Influences | Michael C. Lovell, John Muth |
Influenced |
Costas Azariadis Edward Green Gary Hansen Finn Kydland Rajnish Mehra José Víctor Ríos-Rull V. V. Chari |
Contributions |
Real Business Cycle theory Time consistency in economic policy |
Awards | Nobel Prize in Economics (2004) |
Information at IDEAS / RePEc |
Edward Christian Prescott (born December 26, 1940) is an American economist. He received the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics in 2004, sharing the award with Finn E. Kydland, "for their contributions to dynamic macroeconomics: the time consistency of economic policy and the driving forces behind business cycles". This research was primarily conducted while both Kydland and Prescott were affiliated with the Graduate School of Industrial Administration (now Tepper School of Business) at Carnegie Mellon University. According to the IDEAS/RePEc rankings, he is the 19th most widely cited economist in the world today.[1] In August 2014, Prescott was appointed as an Adjunct Distinguished Economic Professor at the Australian National University (ANU) in Canberra, Australia.
Biography
Early life
Prescott was born in Glens Falls, New York, to Mathilde Helwig Prescott and William Clyde Prescott. In 1962, he received his bachelor's degree in mathematics from Swarthmore College, where he was a member of the Delta Upsilon fraternity. He then received a master's degree from Case Western Reserve University in operations research in 1963, and a PhD in Economics at Carnegie Mellon University in 1967.
Career
From 1966 to 1971, Prescott taught at the University of Pennsylvania. He then returned to Carnegie Mellon until 1980, when he moved to the University of Minnesota, where he taught until 2003. In 1978, he was a visiting professor at the University of Chicago, where he was named a Ford Foundation Research Professor. In the following year, he visited Northwestern University and stayed there until 1982.[2][3] Since 2003, he has been teaching at Arizona State University.
Prescott has been an economic advisor at the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis since 1981.[4] In 2004, he held the Maxwell and Mary Pellish Chair in Economics at the University of California, Santa Barbara.[5] In 2006, he held the Shinsei Bank Visiting Professorship at New York University. In August 2014, Prescott was appointed an Adjunct Distinguished Professor at Research School of Economics (RSE) of the Australian National University.[6]
The Research Papers in Economics project ranked him as the 19th most influential economist in the world as of August 2012 based on his academic contributions.[1] Currently working as an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and as a professor at Arizona State University's W.P. Carey School of Business, he is a major figure in macroeconomics, especially the theories of business cycles and general equilibrium. In his "Rules Rather Than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans," published in 1977 with Finn E. Kydland, he analyzed whether central banks should have strict numerical targets or be allowed to use their discretion in setting monetary policy. He is also well known for his work on the Hodrick-Prescott Filter, used to smooth fluctuations in a time series. Prescott has also expressed skepticism towards fractional reserve banking.[7]
Nobel Prize
Edward Prescott and Finn Kydland Nobel prize for economics was based on two papers Prescott and Kydland wrote. In the first paper, written in 1977 "Rules Rather than Discretion: : The inconsistency of optimal planning" Prescott and Kydland argue that purpose and goals of economic planning and policy is to trigger a desired response from the economy. However, Prescott and Kydland realized that these sectors are made up of individuals, individuals who make assumptions and predictions about the future. As Prescott and Kydland stated “Even if there is a fixed and agreed upon social objective function and policy makers know the timing and magnitude of the effects of their actions... correct evaluation of the end-of-point position does not result in the social objective being maximized.” Prescott and Kyland were pointing out that agents in the economy already factor into their decision making the assumed response by policy makers to a given economic climate.
Additionally Prescott and Kydland felt that the policy makers due to their relationship with government suffered from a credibility issue. The reason for this dynamic is that the political process is designed to fix problems and benefit its citizens today. Prescott and Kydland demonstrated this with a simple yet convincing example. In this example they take an area that has been shown likely to flood (a flood plain) and the government has stated that the “socially optimal outcome” is to not have houses be built in that area and therefore the government states that it will not provide flood protection (dams, levees, and flood insurance) rational agents will not live in that area. However, rational agents are forward planning creatures and know that if they and others build houses in the flood plain the government which makes decisions based on current situations will then provide flood protection in the future. While Prescott never uses these words he is describing a moral hazard.[8]
The second paper, written in 1982, "Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations" Prescott and Kydland argued that shifts in supply typically caused by changes and improvements in technology accounted “Not only long term increases in living standards but also to many of the short term fluctuations in business cycles.” To study this hypothesis Prescott established a model to study the change in output, investment, consumption, labor productivity, and employment, between the end of the Second World War and 1980. Using this model the two economists were able to correlate 70% of the fluctuation in output to changes and growth in technology.[9][10] Their main contribution, however, was the way of modeling macroeconomic variables with microfoundations.
Political activity
In January 2009 Prescott, along with more than 250 other economists and professors,[11] signed an open letter to President Barack Obama opposing the passage of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act. The letter was sponsored by libertarian think tank, the Cato Institute, and was printed as a paid advertisement in several newspapers including the New York Times and the Arizona Republic.[12]
His writings more recently have focused on the negative effect of taxes on the economy in Europe.
Honours and awards
- United States National Academy of Sciences (2008)
- Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (2004)
- Erwin Plein Nemmers Prize in Economics, Northwestern University (2002)
- Fellow, American Academy of Arts and Sciences (1992)
- Fellow, Econometric Society (1980)
- Alexander Henderson Award, Carnegie Mellon (1967)
References
- 1 2 "Economist Rankings at IDEAS – Top 10% Authors, as of February 2013". Research Papers in Economics. February 2013. Retrieved March 9, 2013.
- ↑ "Edward C. Prescott – Autobiography". Nobelprize.org. Retrieved October 19, 2010.
- ↑ "Staff Faculty – Directory – W. P. Carey School of Business". Wpcarey.asu.edu. July 8, 2010. Retrieved October 19, 2010.
- ↑ "Staff Details: Edward C. Prescott, Senior Monetary Advisor". Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Retrieved 1 September 2014.
- ↑ "Finn E. Kydland – 2004 Nobel Prize in Economics". Ucsb.edu. Retrieved October 19, 2010.
- ↑ Australian National University
- ↑ Interview on YouTube
- ↑ http://www.minneapolisfed.org/research/prescott/papers/timetobuild.pdf
- ↑ "web-041003.dvi" (PDF). Retrieved October 19, 2010.
- ↑ http://www.minneapolisfed.org/research/prescott/papers/rulesdiscretion.pdf
- ↑ http://www.cato.org/special/stimulus09/cato_stimulus.pdf
- ↑ House OKs Stimulus Without Any Votes From Republicans at the Wayback Machine (archived January 30, 2009)
Further reading
- Lucas, Robert E, Jr. and Prescott, Edward C. (1971). "Investment Under Uncertainty". Econometrica 39 (5): 659–681. doi:10.2307/1909571. JSTOR 1909571.
- Kehoe, T. J., and E. C. Prescott, editors, Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 2007.
- Kydland, F., and E. C. Prescott (1977). "Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans". Journal of Political Economy: 473–492. doi:10.1086/260580.
- Prescott, Edward C. and Mehra, Rajnish (1980). "Recursive Competitive Equilibrium: The Case of Homogeneous Households". Econometrica 48 (6): 1365–79. doi:10.2307/1912812. JSTOR 1912812.
- Kydland, Finn; E. C. Prescott (1982). "Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations". Econometrica 50 (6): 1345–1370. doi:10.2307/1913386. JSTOR 1913386.
- Mehra, Rajnish; Edward C. Prescott (1985). "The Equity Premium: A Puzzle" (PDF). Journal of Monetary Economics 15 (2): 145–161. doi:10.1016/0304-3932(85)90061-3.
- Kydland, Finn; E. C. Prescott (1990). "Business Cycles: Real Facts and a Monetary Myth". Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review: 3–18.
- Prescott, Edward C. 'More Time on the Job', in The 4% Solution: Unleashing the Economic Growth America Needs, edited by Brendan Miniter. New York: Crown Business. 2012.
External links
- Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
- Nobel Foundation
- IDEAS/RePEc
- Edward C. Prescott (1940– ). The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Library of Economics and Liberty (2nd ed.) (Liberty Fund). 2008.
|
|
|