Technological unemployment

Productivity and employment data since 1947. Proponents of the technological unemployment concept argue that automation is allowing more productivity with fewer workers.
Critics of technological unemployment argue that technology is used by workers and doesn't replace workers on a large scale.

Technological unemployment is unemployment primarily caused by technological change. Early concern about technological unemployment was exemplified by the Luddites, textile workers who feared that automated looms would allow more productivity with fewer workers, leading to mass unemployment. But while automation did lead to textile workers being laid off, new jobs in other industries developed. Due to this shift of labor from automated industries to non-automated industries, technological unemployment has been called the Luddite fallacy.[1][2][3]

Modern proponents of the technological unemployment concept argue that productivity has been decoupling from employment throughout the 21st century, as increasing numbers of industries are automating simultaneously.[4][5] They point to studies showing that the job losses are most concentrated in occupations involving routine physical and mental labor, the jobs that are easiest to automate.[6] The chief insight is that even though it is true that new types of jobs can always develop, the skills of most people may not be adequate to fill many of them. Various ideas on how to bypass this problem exist.

In 2014, Pew Research canvassed 1,896 technology professionals and economists and found a split of opinion: 48 percent of respondents believed that new technologies would displace more jobs than they would create by the year 2025, while 52 percent maintained that they would not.[7]

Views

[If] the Luddite fallacy were true we would all be out of work because productivity has been increasing for two centuries

Alex Tabarrok[8]

John Maynard Keynes used the term as early as 1930, warning: "We are being afflicted with a new disease of which some readers may not yet have heard the name, but of which they will hear a great deal in the years to come – namely, technological unemployment. This means unemployment due to our discovery of means of economizing the use of labor outrunning the pace at which we can find new uses for labor. But this is only a temporary phase of maladjustment"[9]

Economist Alex Tabarrok's summary of the concept states that "[if] the Luddite fallacy were true we would all be out of work because productivity has been increasing for two centuries".[8]

[T]here are more sectors losing jobs than creating jobs. And the general-purpose aspect of software technology means that even the industries and jobs that it creates are not forever.

Lawrence Summers[10]

Former U.S. Treasury Secretary and Harvard economics professor Lawrence Summers argues that this time will be different: "[T]here are many reasons to think the software revolution will be even more profound than the agricultural revolution. This time around, change will come faster and affect a much larger share of the economy. [...] [T]here are more sectors losing jobs than creating jobs. And the general-purpose aspect of software technology means that even the industries and jobs that it creates are not forever. [...] If current trends continue, it could well be that a generation from now a quarter of middle-aged men will be out of work at any given moment."[10]

Labor-displacing technologies can generally be classified under the headings of mechanization, automation, and process improvement. The first two fundamentally involve transferring tasks from humans to machines. The third fundamentally involves the elimination of tasks altogether. The common theme of all three is that tasks are removed from the workforce, decreasing employment. In practice, the categories often overlap: a process improvement can include an automating or mechanizing achievement. The line between mechanization and automation is also subjective, as sometimes mechanization can involve sufficient control to be viewed as part of automation.

Unemployment due to an increment in productivity generates an expectancy that no new jobs, or not enough new jobs, will arise to fill the void. Variants of this argument persist through the present day, as do counter-arguments to it.[11][12] Average working hours have decreased significantly since the advent of modern efficiency producing technologies and continue to fall as less and less labor is needed to meet demand.[13][14]

The notion of technological unemployment leading to structural unemployment (and being macroeconomically injurious) is labelled the Luddite fallacy. If a firm's technological innovation results in a reduction of labor inputs, then the firm's cost of production falls, which shifts the firm's supply curve outward and reduces the price of the good (limited by the price elasticity of demand[15]). The widespread adoption of the innovator's technology could lead to market entry by new firms, partially offsetting the displaced labor, but the main benefit to the innovation is the increase in aggregate demand that results from the price decrease. As long as real prices fall (or real incomes rise), the additional purchasing power gives consumers the ability to purchase more products and services. With technological innovation, these are often products and services new to the consumer, such as better health care or wireless communication devices and services. This increase in aggregate demand leads many economists to believe that technological change, although disruptive of individual careers and particular firms, cannot lead to systemic unemployment, but actually increases employment due to its expansionary effect on the economy.[16] The Economist bases this belief on two assumptions - that machines are used as tools to increase workers' production, and that most workers will be able to operate those machines - and argues that the increase in computerised automation can destroy works in a disruptive way, with the new jobs being out of reach of the capabilities of most workers.[1]

Different views have been expressed on the rate of technological progress, with many, such as C. Owen Paepke, Tyler Cowen, Robert W. Ayres claiming that it is decelerating and others saying technological change is accelerating.[17][18][19] Other economists contend that the rate of technological change has become so rapid in the area of information and communication technologies (ICT) that the adverse latent effects of productivity on employment may outpace job growth in an economy increasingly reliant on the development of these tertiary and quaternary economic sectors.[20][21][22]

The technological acceleration argument is counter to the fact that productivity in developed countries has been slowing down for decades.[23][24] This has been explained in part by the claim that the remainder of labor and energy to be saved in important economic processes is trivial compared to what has already been saved.[17] Examples are agriculture where 98% of the labor has been removed and electrical generation which is approaching thermodynamic limits.[17][25][26][27] Researchers from the University of Chicago have documented a worldwide downwards trend in the share of labor income in the last three decades, in the form of lower wages and benefits with increased inequality across industries, and a rising share going to capital income, beyond what can be explained by recession, and attributed to structural changes in technology, market structures and labor unions.[28]

In principle, technological unemployment may be distinguished from unemployment caused merely by the contraction phases of business cycles. In practice, such differentiation is difficult, owing to the multivariate nature of economics. Like unemployment in general, most technological unemployment is temporary, as unemployed workers eventually find new jobs. For several centuries, the main controversy about technological unemployment has been whether it can ever lead to structural unemployment.

History

Early in the Industrial Revolution

John Kay inventor of the Fly Shuttle, by Ford Madox Brown, depicting the inventor John Kay fleeing a mob intent on destroying his mechanical loom

Historical concerns about the effects of automation date back to the very beginning of the Industrial Revolution, when a social movement of English textile machine operators in the early 19th century known as the Luddites protested against Jacquard's automated weaving looms.[29] The Luddites destroyed a number of these machines, which they felt threatened their jobs.

The original Luddites were hosiery and lace workers in Nottingham, England in 1811. They smashed knitting machines that embodied new labor-saving technology as a protest against unemployment, publicizing their actions in circulars mysteriously signed, "King Ludd".[30]

The Luddite events of 1811 were the beginning of humankind's analysis of whether it is possible for technological unemployment to be other than temporary and confined to particular industries and firms. Contrary to the Luddites' fears, technological advancement did not ruin Britain's economy or systemically lower standards of living throughout the following decades of the 19th century. In fact, during the 19th and 20th centuries, the opposite happened, as technology helped Britain to become much less impoverished than before. For this reason, some economists think that the general Luddite premise is fundamentally flawed, and thus they apply the term Luddite fallacy to it. Economist Alex Tabarrok summarises the fallacy as:

If the Luddite fallacy were true we would all be out of work because productivity has been increasing for two centuries.[8]

Ronnie Bray writes:

The 'Luddite Fallacy' referred to here fallaciously misdirects the reader's attention away from the major objection and opposition raised by Luddites to the introduction of machines in textile and related industries. All available Luddite literature, usually in the form of popular songs, protest songs, and broadsheets, shows that unemployment, poverty, and starvation were their major concerns. Thus, it is wrong to label them as anti-technology because they were anti-starvation. The difference is not wasted on those that have endured starvation. It is right to say that for the most part they saw power looms, cropping frames, and mechanical knitting frames, as the direct cause of unemployment, which condition led to cessation of income, which led directly to starvation in short time. It cannot be doubted that had mechanisation either maintained or increased the level of employment in the affected industries, that there would have been no uprising on account of mechanisation.[31]

Kevin Binfield, Eric Hobsbawm and Richard Conniff wrote that the Luddites were not technophobes. They added that the machines suppressed workers' wages at a time when the Luddites, who were artisans and highly skilled workers relying on their wages to buy food, especially feared famine due to rising food prices. This made the machines the most accessible target for the Luddites' angry expression of that fear.[32][33][34]

During the Machine Age

As in the preceding century, the period from the 1880s to the late 1920s saw no underlying automation-induced structural lack of new economic opportunities for skilled workers given enough time for searching.[35] The Great Depression then caused a tremendous disruption in employment; but the foundational potential for full employment had not been lost, as would later be shown by the post–World War II economic expansion and other economic miracles. (See: Economic stagnation#The end of the stagnation in the U.S. following the Great Depression).

In the 1930s, John Maynard Keynes predicted that a century later there would be a 15-hour work week, as the "economic problem" would be replaced by the problem of leisure.[36]

1950s to present

The 1950s and 60s were optimistic economic times in many respects, and during this era many optimists made forecasts similar to Keynes's 1930s discussion of a pending abundance of leisure time. Meanwhile, pessimists questioned the role of labor in such a world and how people would earn a living or occupy their time. During the 1960s, economic growth did lead to a rise in real income per capita and a decline in the average number of work hours per week; yet, real income and the length of the work week have remained relatively constant in the United States since then, even after the influx of a large number of women into the workforce.[37]

Despite the elimination of manual labour and assembly line jobs after World War II via advancing mechanization and automation, employment in the services sector (tertiary sector) absorbed the displaced labor from the industrial sector (secondary sector). For example, many manufacturing jobs left the United States during the 1990s but were offset by a one-time massive increase in Information technology ("IT") jobs at the same time. In some cases, freeing up of the labor force allows more people to enter higher-skilled managerial jobs and technologically-specialized jobs, which are typically higher paying.

Works by scholars David F. Noble[38] and Jeremy Rifkin[39] are dedicated to study the social history of automation and the potential impact of scientific and technological changes on the economy. They are sometimes mocked with the disparaging label "neo-Luddite".

Post-market theories

Rifkin's The End of Work, published in 1995, predicted that automation-induced unemployment would begin to be widespread within the following decade due to the sudden and massive development of informational technology. The book focuses mostly on robotics, mentioning the Internet once in passing and the World Wide Web not at all. It calls the new era the "post-market economy",[39] although it does not offer details on what should replace the market. Political philosopher George Caffentzis identified Rifkin as "major participant in the "end of work" discourse of the 1990s" and discounted his argument as "not taking into account the dynamics of employment and technological change in the capitalist era".

Market-based ideas (People's Capitalism, new-market theories, others)

James S. Albus, a United States government engineer and pioneering inventor in automation, robotics and other intelligent systems, was concerned for many years about the potential social impact of advanced intelligent systems.[40][41][42] Dr. Albus was optimistic about the wealth producing capabilities of intelligent machines but concerned about the elimination of jobs and downward pressure advanced automation placed on human wages and incomes. In his 1976 book titled Peoples' Capitalism: The Economics of the Robot Revolution[40] and on his websites,[41][43] Albus lays out a plan to broaden capital ownership to the point where every citizen becomes a capitalist with a substantial income from personal ownership of capital assets. This would achieve an economic system where income from ownership of capital assets would supplement—and eventually supplant—wages and salaries as the primary source of income for the average citizen. Albus believes this would lead to a world of prosperity and opportunity without poverty, war or pollution.

Marshall Brain[2] and Martin Ford,[3] author of the 2009 book The Lights in the Tunnel: Automation, Accelerating Technology and the Economy of the Future are IT engineers who worry that advancing IT will displace workers faster than current economic structures can absorb them back into the economy. Ford presents an argument[3] for why the fear of disruption to employment, although fallacious for two centuries, might nevertheless become valid as the speed of development of new machine technology differs substantially from the past. He compares this to the standard warning in financial prospectuses that "past performance is not a guarantee of future results". Brain and Ford both advocate pursuing some permutation of basic income or guaranteed minimum income, simply to keep the recirculation of value throughout the economy from stalling due to low employment. Although the earliest variants of these ideas involve direct support from the government, which could tax highly automated companies and use the revenue for both basic income and select reemployment, they have also evolved to include market-based mechanisms, comparable to minimum wage laws, requiring the private sector to employ humans but leaving the job descriptions to private innovation. In these lines of thinking, it is recognized that the "lump of labour" is a fallacy and that automation can continue to yield ever higher per capita standards of living (both facts being in contrast to what Luddites thought), but also that the kinds of labor involved in newly created job categories may be of types that most people may not be qualified to do. (For example, jobs for highly skilled information technologists, such as robotics engineers or systems integrators, may be in high demand, but most people will be unable to do them.[44]) To bypass this problem, the basic income or new markets decouple consumer purchasing power and confidence from the traditional labor market, which can suffer from fluctuations in the business cycle or (as Ford argues) even potential market failure. In its place would grow a new labor market insulated from these concerns.

In their books The Second Machine Age: Work, Progress, and Prosperity in a Time of Brilliant Technologies and Race Against The Machine: How the Digital Revolution is Accelerating Innovation, Driving Productivity, and Irreversibly Transforming Employment and the Economy, MIT professors Andrew McAfee and Erik Brynjolfsson write that the pace of automation has picked up in recent years due to a combination of increasingly clever advanced digital technologies. They write these technologies are making people more innovative, productive and financially richer, both in the short- and long-term, but at the cost of increasing wealth inequality in society. In the authors' view, one of the main in-egalitarian consequences of digital technological developments is its potentially negative impact on well-paid employment. The authors recommend governments consider modifying public education systems to place greater emphasis on teaching creativity and entrepreneurship, increasing investments in infrastructure and basic research, and revising tax policies to reward employers for hiring people and to increase the tax rates on wealthy individuals.[45][46] The authors advocate for a collaborative partnership between computers and humans as the road to future job creation. "In medicine, law, finance, retailing, manufacturing and even scientific discovery," they write, "the key to winning the race is not to compete against machines but to compete with machines."[47][48][49][50][51]

Larry Summers wrote about the "devastating consequences" of robots, 3-D printing, artificial intelligence, and similar technologies for those who perform routine tasks. In his view, "already there are more American men on disability insurance than doing production work in manufacturing. And the trends are all in the wrong direction, particularly for the less skilled, as the capacity of capital embodying artificial intelligence to replace white-collar as well as blue-collar work will increase rapidly in the years ahead." Summers recommends more vigorous cooperative efforts to address the "myriad devices" (e.g. tax havens, bank secrecy, money laundering, and regulatory arbitrage) enabling the holders of great wealth to "avoid paying" income and estate taxes, and to make it more difficult to accumulate great fortunes without requiring "great social contributions" in return, including: more vigorous enforcement of anti-monopoly laws, reductions in "excessive" protection for intellectual property, greater encouragement of profit-sharing schemes that may benefit workers and give them a stake in wealth accumulation, strengthening of collective bargaining arrangements, improvements in corporate governance, strengthening of financial regulation to eliminate subsidies to financial activity, easing of land-use restrictions that may cause the real estate of the rich to keep rising in value, better training for young people and retraining for displaced workers, and increased public and private investment in infrastructure development, e.g. in energy production and transportation.[52] Summers also said he no longer believed automation would always create new jobs. "This isn’t some hypothetical future possibility. This is something that’s emerging before us right now." He added the answer is not to try to stop technological change, "but the answer is not to just suppose that everything’s going to be O.K. because the magic of the market will assure that’s true."[53]

Michael Spence wrote that "Now comes a ... powerful, wave of digital technology that is replacing labor in increasingly complex tasks. This process of labor substitution and disintermediation has been underway for some time in service sectors – think of ATMs, online banking, enterprise resource planning, customer relationship management, mobile payment systems, and much more. This revolution is spreading to the production of goods, where robots and 3D printing are displacing labor." In his view, the vast majority of the cost of digital technologies comes at the start, in the design of hardware (e.g. sensors) and, more important, in creating the software that enables machines to carry out various tasks. "Once this is achieved, the marginal cost of the hardware is relatively low (and declines as scale rises), and the marginal cost of replicating the software is essentially zero. With a huge potential global market to amortize the upfront fixed costs of design and testing, the incentives to invest [in digital technologies] are compelling." Spence believes that, unlike prior digital technologies, which drove firms to deploy underutilized pools of valuable labor around the world, the motivating force in the current wave of digital technologies "is cost reduction via the replacement of labor." For example, as the cost of 3D printing technology declines, it is "easy to imagine" that production may become "extremely" local and customized. Moreover, production may occur in response to actual demand, not anticipated or forecast demand. "Meanwhile, the impact of robotics ... is not confined to production. Though self-driving cars and drones are the most attention-getting examples, the impact on logistics is no less transformative. Computers and robotic cranes that schedule and move containers around and load ships now control the Port of Singapore, one of the most efficient in the world." Spence believes that labor, no matter how inexpensive, will become a less important asset for growth and employment expansion, with labor-intensive, process-oriented manufacturing becoming less effective, and that re-localization will appear globally. In his view, production will not disappear, but it will be less labor-intensive, and all countries will eventually need to rebuild their growth models around digital technologies and the human capital supporting their deployment and expansion. Spence writes that "the world we are entering is one in which the most powerful global flows will be ideas and digital capital, not goods, services, and traditional capital. Adapting to this will require shifts in mindsets, policies, investments (especially in human capital), and quite possibly models of employment and distribution."[54]

In a talk on four of the most dominant companies in the digital economy, Scott Galloway of the New York University Stern School of Business said that "the smartphone economy is going to be outstanding for employment and it's going to be terrible for wages."[55]

Ryan Avent, an economics correspondent for The Economist, reports that one possible solution may be to restore some of the labor market regulations that protected workers in previous decades. However, in Avent's view, this could increase the cost of labor, which could increase firms' interest in substituting labor-saving technologies for workers, potentially canceling out the beneficial effects. Another option may be to improve workers' education. And a third option may be a form of redistribution, by giving workers a share of ownership in the corporation, or by increasing taxes on the owners of capital and distributing the funds to workers.[56]

Google’s co-founder, Larry Page, suggested a four-day workweek, so as technology displaces jobs, more people can find employment.[53][57][58]

Non-market-based ideas

Albert Einstein wrote that "Technological progress frequently results in more unemployment rather than in an easing of the burden of work for all." He proposed the "establishment of a socialist economy," together with an educational system focused on social goals.[59]

John Lanchester wrote that "There is a possible alternative, however, in which ownership and control of robots is disconnected from capital in its current form. The robots liberate most of humanity from work, and everybody benefits from the proceeds: we don’t have to work in factories or go down mines or clean toilets or drive long-distance lorries, but we can choreograph and ... invent things ... It seems to me that the only way that world would work is with alternative forms of ownership ... This alternative future would be the kind of world dreamed of by William Morris ... Except with added robots ..."[60]

See also

References

  1. 1.0 1.1 Babbage Science and technology (2011-11-04). "Artificial intelligence: Difference Engine: Luddite legacy". The Economist. Retrieved 2013-03-28.
  2. 2.0 2.1 Brain 2003.
  3. 3.0 3.1 3.2 Ford 2009.
  4. Erik Brynjolfsson; Andrew McAfee (11 December 2012). "Jobs, Productivity and the Great Decoupling". The New York Times. Retrieved 14 August 2014.
  5. "Business output and total employment (nonfarm)". FRED: Federal Reserve Economic Data. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Retrieved 14 August 2014.
  6. Nisen, Max (28 July 2014). "Automation + recessions = a radical shift in the shape of America's jobs market". Quartz. Retrieved 19 August 2014.
  7. Smith, Aaron; Anderson, Janna (6 August 2014). "AI, Robotics, and the Future of Jobs". Pew Research Center. Retrieved 14 August 2014.
  8. 8.0 8.1 8.2 Tabarrok, Alex (2003-12-31). "Productivity and unemployment". Marginal Revolution. Retrieved 2007-03-11.
  9. Keynes, John Maynard (1930). Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren (PDF).
  10. 10.0 10.1 Lawrence H. Summers (7 July 2014). "Lawrence H. Summers on the Economic Challenge of the Future: Jobs". Retrieved 22 August 2014.
  11. Roberts 2011.
  12. Lyons 2011.
  13. "Hours of Work in U.S. History". Economic History Association. 2010-02-01.
  14. Whaples, Robert (June 1991). "The Shortening of the American Work Week: An Economic and Historical Analysis of Its Context, Causes, and Consequences". The Journal of Economic History (Cambridge University Press) 51 (2): 454–457. doi:10.1017/s0022050700039073. JSTOR 2122588.
  15. Jerome, Harry (1934). Mechanization in Industry, National Bureau of Economic Research (PDF).
  16. N.V. (Nov 4, 2011). "Difference Engine: Luddite legacy". Babbage (blog) (The Economist).
  17. 17.0 17.1 17.2 Paepke, C. Owen. The Evolution of Progress: The End of Economic Growth and the Beginning of Human Transformation. New York, Toronto: Random House. ISBN 0-679-41582-3.
  18. Ayres, Robert U. (1998). Turning Point: An End to the Growth Paradigm. London: Earthscan Publications. ISBN 978-1-85383-439-4.
  19. The Great Stagnation: How America Ate All the Low-Hanging Fruit of Modern History, Got Sick, and Will (Eventually) Feel Better. Dutton Adult. 2011. ISBN 978-0525952718.
  20. R.A. (Nov 9, 2011). "Race against the machine". Free exchange (blog) (The Economist).
  21. "When Machines Do The Work". On Point with Tom Ashbrook. 90.9 WBUR (Boston NPR). November 2, 2011.
  22. http://ebusiness.mit.edu/research/Briefs/Brynjolfsson_McAfee_Race_Against_the_Machine.pdf
  23. Kendrick, John (1991). "U.S. Productivity Performance in Perspective, Business Economics, October 1, 1991".
  24. Field, Alezander J. (2007). "U.S. Economic Growth in the Gilded Age, Journal of Macroeconomics 31". pp. 173–190.
  25. Ayres, Rober U; Ayres, Leslie W; Warr, Benjamin (2002), "Exergy, Power and Work in the US Economy, 1900-1998" (PDF), Working paper (INSEAD's Center for the Management of Environmental Resources (CMER)), retrieved 22 November 2010
  26. Ayres, Robert U; Warr, Benjamin (2009), The Economic Growth Engine: How Energy and Work Drive Material Prosperity, Cheltenham, UK & Northampton, Massachusetts: Edward Elgar Publishing, ISBN 978-1-84844-182-8, retrieved 22 November 2010
  27. Bruce Bartlett (June 25, 2013). "Labor’s Declining Share Is an International Problem". The New York Times. Retrieved 9 September 2013.
  28. "The Luddites". Spartacus.schoolnet.co.uk. Retrieved 2013-03-28.
  29. Easterly, William (2001). The Elusive Quest for Growth: Economists' Adventures and Misadventures in the Tropics. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press. pp. 53–54. ISBN 0-262-55042-3.
  30. Bray, Ronnie. Luddite Spring — The Huddersfield Luddite Uprising of 1811-1812.
  31. Binfield, Kevin (2004). Writings of the Luddites. Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press, 2004. ISBN 0-8018-7612-5
  32. Conniff, Richard (March 2011). What the Luddites Really Fought Against. "The label now has many meanings, but when the group protested 200 years ago, technology wasn't really the enemy." Smithsonian magazine
  33. Harford, Tim (March 2015). Man v machine (again). "The Luddite anxiety has been dormant for many years but has recently enjoyed a resurgence." Financial Times Magazine
  34. Hartness 1910, p. 7–12
  35. Elliott, Larry (1 September 2008). "Economics: Whatever happened to Keynes' 15-hour working week?". The Guardian (London). Retrieved 17 April 2012.
  36. Hayes B. (2009). Automation on the Job. American Scientist.
  37. Noble 1984.
  38. 39.0 39.1 Rifkin 1995.
  39. 40.0 40.1 James S. Albus, Peoples' Capitalism: The Economics of the Robot Revolution (free download)
  40. 41.0 41.1 James S. Albus, People's Capitalism main website
  41. James S. Albus Curriculum Vitae
  42. "Dr. James Albus". James-albus.org. Retrieved 2013-03-28.
  43. The Four Horsemen: Amazon, Apple, Facebook and Google -- Who Wins/Loses, a talk by Scott Galloway at the Digital Life Design (DLD) 2015 Annual Conference. Posted on the official You Tube Channel of DLD
  44. Ascher Schechter, After the Working Class, Technology is Eliminating the Middle Class, TheMarker, 2013.01.11. Quotations and citations in this Wikipedia article are based on the translation from Hebrew to English of the TheMarker article.
  45. Ascher Schechter, Are You Ready for the Age of the Smart Machines?, TheMarker, 2014.04.26. Quotations and citations in this Wikipedia article are based on the translation from Hebrew to English of the TheMarker article.
  46. Steve Lohr, More Jobs Predicted for Machines, Not People, book review in The New York Times, 2011.10.23
  47. Andrew Keen, Keen On How The Internet Is Making Us Both Richer and More Unequal (TCTV), interview with Andrew McAfee and Erik Brynjolfsson, TechCrunch, 2011.11.15
  48. JILL KRASNY, MIT Professors: The 99% Should Shake Their Fists At The Tech Boom, Business Insider, 2011.11.25
  49. Scott Timberg, The Clerk, RIP, Salon.com, 2011.12.18
  50. Andrew Leonard, Robots are stealing your job: How technology threatens to wipe out the middle class, Salon.com, 2014.01.17
  51. Larry Summers, The Inequality Puzzle, Democracy: A Journal of Ideas, Issue #32, Spring 2014
  52. 53.0 53.1 As Robots Grow Smarter, American Workers Struggle to Keep Up (2014-12-15), The New York Times
  53. Michael Spence, Labor’s Digital Displacement (2014-05-22), Project Syndicate
  54. The Four Horsemen: Amazon, Apple, Facebook and Google -- Who Wins/Loses, a talk by Scott Galloway at the Digital Life Design (DLD) 2015 Annual Conference. Posted on the official You Tube Channel of DLD
  55. Labour's Declining Share - A Spectre to Worry About?, The Economist, 2013.11.05
  56. Larry Page discusses his views on the socio-economic effects of advanced intelligent systems and how advanced digital technologies can be used to create abundance (as described in Peter Diamandis' book), provide for people's needs, shorten the workweek, and mitigate any potential detrimental effects of technological unemployment. 2014-07-03. Discussion with Sergey Brin and Vinod Khosla. Starting at about 13:00 into the video. The audience is composed of the CEOs of the portfolio companies of Khosla Ventures.
  57. FT interview with Google co-founder and CEO Larry Page (2014-10-31), The Financial Times
  58. Einstein, Albert (May 1949, republished May 1998 and May 2009), Why Socialism?, Vol. 1, No. 1, Monthly Review
  59. Lanchester, John (March 2015). The Robots Are Coming, Vol. 37, No. 5, pages 3-8, London Review of Books

Bibliography

Further reading

External links