Robert H. Frank

Robert Harris Frank (born January 2, 1945)[1][2] is the Henrietta Johnson Louis Professor of Management and a Professor of Economics at the Samuel Curtis Johnson Graduate School of Management at Cornell University. He contributes to the "Economic View" column, which appears every fifth Sunday in The New York Times. Frank's 2011 book is on wealth inequality in the United States.[3]

Career

Born in Coral Gables, Florida, Frank graduated from Coral Gables High School in 1962.[1][4] Frank received a B.S. in mathematics from the Georgia Institute of Technology in 1966, M.A. in statistics from the University of California, Berkeley in 1971, and Ph.D. in economics from UC Berkeley in 1972.[5][6] Until 2001, he was the Goldwin Smith Professor of Economics, Ethics, and Public Policy in the Cornell University College of Arts and Sciences. For the 2008–09 academic year, Frank was a visiting professor at the New York University Stern School of Business.[1]

Frank has also been a Peace Corps volunteer in rural Nepal, the chief economist for the Civil Aeronautics Board, a fellow at the Center for Advanced Study in the Behavioral Sciences (1992 to 1993), and a Professor of American Civilization at École des hautes études en sciences sociales in Paris (2000–01).[1]

In 2008, Robert H. Frank received an honorary doctorate in Economics from the University of St. Gallen.[7]

Notable theories

Positional arms race

Further information: Expenditure cascades

This theory is an analytical examination of the socioeconomic concept of keeping up with the Joneses and conspicuous consumption. His book Choosing the Right Pond discusses the importance of status, and how much people pay for status. Frank argues that the race for status is bad for society as a whole, as there cannot be improvement in overall status available, because every time person A rises above person B, the sum of their status remains the same. The only thing that changes is which person is where in the hierarchy.

He reasons that this race for status explains partly why increases in wealth do not increase well-being, or do not increase it much. According to Frank, if most earnings are spent on pursuing status, there will not be much improvement in intrinsic quality of life.

Winner take all

In his book The Winner-Take-All Society, he discusses the contemporary trend toward concentration of wealth. He argues that more and more of the current economy and other institutions are moving toward a state where very few winners take very much, while the rest are left with little. He attributes this, in part, to the modern structure of markets and technology.

The strategic role of emotions

In various economic papers and in the book Passions Within Reason, he discusses the idea that emotions have important roles in decision making and personal interactions, even when they seem to be irrational. For example, the emotions of love give more value to long term romantic commitment. A "rational" person would dump his partner as soon as he found a better partnership. Emotional attachment gives more long term meaning to the relationship. Put poetically: "Those sensible about love are incapable of it." Similarly, anger can be used as a precommitment device. Frank states that envy can be useful in that it enforces more fair distributions. By acting "irrationally" when treated unfairly, a person can obtain better results in situations which resemble the ultimatum game if their opponent anticipates their emotional response and adjusts their strategy accordingly.

Prisoner's dilemma and cooperation

Frank, Gilovich, and Regan (1993) conducted an experimental study of the prisoner's dilemma. The subjects were students in their first and final years of undergraduate economics, and undergraduates in other disciplines. Subjects were paired, placed in a typical game scenario, then asked to choose either to "cooperate" or to "defect". Pairs of subjects were told that if they both chose "defect" the payoff for each would be 1. If both cooperated, the payoff for each would be 2. If one defected and the other cooperated, the payoff would be 3 for the defector and 0 for the cooperator. Each subject in a pair made his choice without knowing what the other member of the pair chose.

First year economics students, and students doing disciplines other than economics, overwhelmingly chose to cooperate. But 4th year students in economics tended to not cooperate. Frank et al. concluded, that with "an eye toward both the social good and the well-being of their own students, economists may wish to stress a broader view of human motivation in their teaching."

Negative effects of studying economics

In a highly cited work, Frank showed that the study of economics reduces cooperation in games. The idea is that much of the time cooperation and consideration of others' perspective are irrational in the narrow sense of the word. Thus, learning that cooperation is irrational in some games is influencing the behavior of the students, presumably to the negative.

Publications

Books

Articles

References

  1. 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3 "Robert H. Frank". Who's Who in America, 65th edition. Accessed via LexisNexis on March 25, 2013.
  2. http://www.worldcat.org/title/microeconomics-and-behavior/oclc/750679354
  3. http://www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2012/feb/23/were-more-unequal-you-think/
  4. "Gables High leads county in Merit Semifinalists" (PDF). Coral Gables High Lights. October 5, 1961.
  5. Principles of Macroeconomics. Google Books. 2008-09-26. ISBN 9780073362656. Retrieved 2011-07-14.
  6. Robert H. Frank curriculum vitae
  7. http://www.unisg.ch/en/Schools/Economics+and+Political+Science/Ueber+SEPS/Dozierende/Ehrendoktorate.aspx
  8. Received the following reviews:
    • New York Times Notable Book of the Year, 1995;
    • Business Week Top Ten Books of 1995;
    • San Francisco Review of Books Critics Choice Award, 1995;
    • China Times Top Ten Books of 1996;
    • The London Observer Best Books of the Year List, 1996

External links