Law of one price

The law of one price (LOP) is an economic concept which posits that "a good must sell for the same price in all locations".[1] The law of one price constitutes the basis of the theory of purchasing power parity and is derived from the no arbitrage assumption (see Intuition).

Intuition

The intuition behind the law of one price is based on the assumption that differences between prices are eliminated by market participants taking advantage of arbitrage opportunities.[2]

Assume different prices for a single identical good in two locations, no transport costs and no economic barriers between both locations. The arbitrage mechanism can now be performed by both the supply and/or the demand site: All sellers have an incentive to sell their goods in the higher-priced location, driving up supply in that location and reducing supply in the lower-priced location. If demand remains constant, the higher supply will force prices to decrease in the higher-priced location, while the lowered supply in the alternative location will drive up prices there. Conversely, if all consumers move to the lower-priced location in order to buy the good at the lower price, demand will increase in the lower-priced location, and - assuming constant supply in both locations - prices will increase, whereas the decreased demand in the higher-priced location leads the prices to decrease there. Both scenarios result in a single, equal price per homogeneous good in all locations.[2]

In efficient markets the convergence on one price is instant. For further discussion, please refer to Rational pricing.

Example: financial markets

Commodities can be traded on financial markets, where there will be a single offer price (asking price), and bid price. Although there is a small spread between these two values the law of one price applies (to each). No trader will sell the commodity at a lower price than the market maker's bid-level or buy at a higher price than the market maker's offer-level.[2] In either case moving away from the prevailing price would either leave no takers, or be charity.

In the derivatives market the law applies to financial instruments which appear different, but which resolve to the same set of cash flows; see Rational pricing. Thus:

"A security must have a single price, no matter how that security is created. For example, if an option can be created using two different sets of underlying securities, then the total price for each would be the same or else an arbitrage opportunity would exist.[3]"

A similar argument can be used by considering arrow securities as alluded to by Arrow and Debreu (1944).

Where the law does not apply

Apparent violations

See also

References

  1. Mankiw, N. G. (2011). Principles of Economics (6th ed.). Mason, OH: South-Western Cengage Learning. Page 686.
  2. 2.0 2.1 2.2 Karl Gunnar Persson (10 February 2008). "Definitions and Explanation of the Law of One Price". eh.net. Economic History Services. Retrieved 28 September 2014.
  3. Investors World
  4. Burdett, Kenneth, and Kenneth Judd (1983), 'Equilibrium price dispersion'. Econometrica 51 (4), pp. 955-69.
  5. Lamont, O.A. and Thaler, R.H. (2003), "Anomalies: The Law of One Price in Financial Markets". Journal of Economic Perspectives 17 (Fall 2003), pp. 191–202.