Vanishing Hand

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

The Vanishing Hand theory is a concept first conceived of by economist Richard Normand Langlois.[1] The term is an intentional play on both Adam Smith's Invisible Hand and Alfred Chandler's Visible Hand.[1]

Background

In Smith's work, his Invisible Hand describes the self-regulating behavior of the market. In essence, this theory states that individual personal motivations lead to the most efficient allocation of resources and greatest overall benefit, even if those motivations were not in any way benevolent. This is exemplified by relatively small firms operating with no market control. Competition between buyers and sellers channels the profit motive causing competition to lead to socially desirable outcomes.[2] During Smith's time and much after, this was a justification for a laissez-faire economy. However, in Smith's day there were not several market forces that currently exist, such as large-scale industry, finance, and adverstising.[1][3]

The Visible hand, however, was believed by Chandler to have replaced the Invisible hand with middle management in the mid 19th century, which became “the most powerful institution in the American economy”.[4] In short, he states that the multi-unit business structure arose because administrative coordination could yield greater profits than market coordination, giving rise to managerial hierarchy and led to furthered growth and profit. The rise of this new system yielded major sectors of the economy being dominated and altered the structure of markets, steering away from a competitive state and to an economy controlled by corporate managers. In other words, the large scale industries arising began to provide larger social benefits due to managerial presence and long-term scope rather than perfectly competitive markets.[1][5]

Vanishing Hand Theory

Langlois intended to show that Chandler's theory was partially correct but needed some reevaluation.[6][7]

The Vanishing Hand theory is stated as follows:

“Driven by increases in population and income and by the reduction of technological and legal barriers to trade, the Smithian process of the division of labor always tends to lead to finer specialization of function and increased coordination through markets... But the components of that process — technology, organization, and institutions — change at different rates.  The managerial revolution Chandler chronicles was the result of such an imbalance, in this case between the coordination needs of high-throughput technologies and the abilities of contemporary markets and contemporary institutions to meet those needs.  It was an organizational solution appropriate to its time and place.  But with further growth in the extent of the market and the evolution of institutions to support exchange, the central management of vertically integrated production stages is increasingly succumbing to the forces of specialization.”[6]

In other words, the Vanishing hand theory states that initially the Visible hand is present as industries require managerial cooperation and vertical integration for long term growth, but eventually fades away to a more Invisible hand in which specialization allows for market forces to coordinate more effectively leading to a quasi-Smithian division of labor.[6] Temporary clusters of firms arose acting under Chandler's Visible hand process that would eventually be replaced by Smith's division of labor and thus Invisible hand.[8] Much of the large, vertically-integrated corporations of the past have broken up in recent years into more specialized firms due to the removal of barriers to trade, such as outsourcing. Specifically it has once more become economically optimal to seek a division of labor, or seek Vertical disintegration, rather than integrate.[1]

As minimum efficient scale falls firms size should fall as well. When firm size is viewed as firm activity undertaken, this holds true.[7] It is likely, therefore, that as integration becomes costlier in comparison to alternatives, large firms are more likely disintegrate to varying degrees and have a loosened managerial presence, although complete return to a Smithian market is unlikely.[7]

References

  1. 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 "Technology and the Vanishing Hand". The Past Speaks. 
  2. Sen, Amartya. Introduction. The Theory of Moral Sentiments. By Adam Smith. 6th ed. 1790. New York: Penguin, 2009. vii–xxix.
  3. Olsen, James Stewart. Encyclopedia of the Industrial Revolution. Greenwood Publishing Group, 2002. pp. 153–154
  4. "Harvard Business School Professor Alfred D. Chandler, Jr., Preeminent Business Historian, Dead at 88". AScribe   via HighBeam Research (subscription required) . May 11, 2007. Retrieved December 9, 2012. 
  5. Chandler, Alfred. The Visible Hand. Belknap Press, 1977. ISBN 978-0674940529. Introduction.
  6. 6.0 6.1 6.2 Langlois, Richard N. (Apr 2003). "The Vanishing Hand: the Changing Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism". Industrial and Corporate Change 12(2): 351-385. 
  7. 7.0 7.1 7.2 Langlois, Dick (Jul 3, 2010). "More on Managerial Coordination and the Vanishing Hand". Organizations and Markets. 
  8. "The vanishing hand: the changing dynamics of industrial capitalism". Industrial and Corporate Change. 
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike; additional terms may apply for the media files.