Dynamic risk measure

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

In financial mathematics, a conditional risk measure is a random variable of the financial risk (particularly the downside risk) as if measured at some point in the future. A risk measure can be thought of as a conditional risk measure on the trivial sigma algebra.

A dynamic risk measure is a risk measure that deals with the question of how evaluations of risk at different times are related. It can be interpreted as a sequence of conditional risk measures. [1]

Conditional risk measure

A mapping \rho _{t}:L^{{\infty }}\left({\mathcal  {F}}_{T}\right)\rightarrow L_{t}^{{\infty }}=L^{{\infty }}\left({\mathcal  {F}}_{t}\right) is a conditional risk measure if it has the following properties:

Conditional cash invariance
\forall m_{t}\in L_{t}^{{\infty }}:\;\rho _{t}(X+m_{t})=\rho _{t}(X)-m_{t}
Monotonicity
{\mathrm  {If}}\;X\leq Y\;{\mathrm  {then}}\;\rho _{t}(X)\geq \rho _{t}(Y)
Normalization
\rho _{t}(0)=0

If it is a conditional convex risk measure then it will also have the property:

Conditional convexity
\forall \lambda \in L_{t}^{{\infty }},0\leq \lambda \leq 1:\rho _{t}(\lambda X+(1-\lambda )Y)\leq \lambda \rho _{t}(X)+(1-\lambda )\rho _{t}(Y)

A conditional coherent risk measure is a conditional convex risk measure that additionally satisfies:

Conditional positive homogeneity
\forall \lambda \in L_{t}^{{\infty }},\lambda \geq 0:\rho _{t}(\lambda X)=\lambda \rho _{t}(X)

Acceptance set

The acceptance set at time t associated with a conditional risk measure is

A_{t}=\{X\in L_{T}^{{\infty }}:\rho (X)\leq 0{\text{ a.s.}}\}.

If you are given an acceptance set at time t then the corresponding conditional risk measure is

\rho _{t}={\text{ess}}\inf\{Y\in L_{t}^{{\infty }}:X+Y\in A_{t}\}

where {\text{ess}}\inf is the essential infimum.[2]

Regular property

A conditional risk measure \rho _{t} is said to be regular if for any X\in L_{T}^{{\infty }} and A\in {\mathcal  {F}}_{t} then \rho _{t}(1_{A}X)=1_{A}\rho _{t}(X) where 1_{A} is the indicator function on A. Any normalized conditional convex risk measure is regular.[3]

The financial interpretation of this states that the conditional risk at some future node (i.e. \rho _{t}(X)[\omega ]) only depends on the possible states from that node. In a binomial model this would be akin to calculating the risk on the subtree branching off from the point in question.

Time consistent property

A dynamic risk measure is time consistent if and only if \rho _{{t+1}}(X)\leq \rho _{{t+1}}(Y)\Rightarrow \rho _{t}(X)\leq \rho _{t}(Y)\;\forall X,Y\in L^{{0}}({\mathcal  {F}}_{T}).[4]

Example: dynamic superhedging price

The dynamic superhedging price has conditional risk measures of the form: \rho _{t}(-X)=\operatorname *{ess\sup }_{{Q\in EMM}}{\mathbb  {E}}^{Q}[X|{\mathcal  {F}}_{t}]. It is a widely shown result that this is also a time consistent risk measure.

References

  1. Acciaio, Beatrice; Penner, Irina (February 22, 2010). Dynamic risk measures (pdf). Retrieved July 22, 2010. 
  2. Penner, Irina (2007). Dynamic convex risk measures: time consistency, prudence, and sustainability (pdf). Retrieved February 3, 2011. 
  3. Detlefsen, K.; Scandolo, G. (2005). "Conditional and dynamic convex risk measures". Finance and Stochastics 9 (4): 539–561. 
  4. Cheridito, Patrick; Stadje, Mitja (October 2008). Time-inconsistency of VaR and time-consistent alternatives. 
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike; additional terms may apply for the media files.