Computable general equilibrium

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Computable general equilibrium (CGE) models are a class of economic models that use actual economic data to estimate how an economy might react to changes in policy, technology or other external factors. CGE models are also referred to as AGE (applied general equilibrium) models.

Overview

A CGE model consists of (a) equations describing model variables and (b) a database (usually very detailed) consistent with the model equations. The equations tend to be neo-classical in spirit, often assuming cost-minimizing behaviour by producers, average-cost pricing, and household demands based on optimizing behaviour. However, most CGE models conform only loosely to the theoretical general equilibrium paradigm. For example, they may allow for:

  1. non-market clearing, especially for labour (unemployment) or for commodities (inventories)
  2. imperfect competition (e.g., monopoly pricing)
  3. demands not influenced by price (e.g., government demands)
  4. a range of taxes
  5. externalities, such as pollution

A CGE model database consists of:

  1. tables of transaction values, showing, for example, the value of coal used by the iron industry. Usually the database is presented as an input-output table or as a social accounting matrix. In either case, it covers the whole economy of a country (or even the whole world), and distinguishes a number of sectors, commodities, primary factors and perhaps types of household.
  2. elasticities: dimensionless parameters that capture behavioural response. For example, export demand elasticities specify by how much export volumes might fall if export prices went up. Other elasticities may belong to the Constant Elasticity of Substitution class. Amongst these are Armington elasticities, which show whether products of different countries are close substitutes, and elasticities measuring how easily inputs to production may be substituted for one another. Expenditure elasticities show how household demands respond to income changes.

CGE models are descended from the input-output models pioneered by Wassily Leontief, but assign a more important role to prices. Thus, where Leontief assumed that, say, a fixed amount of labour was required to produce a ton of iron, a CGE model would normally allow wage levels to (negatively) affect labour demands.

CGE models derive too from the models for planning the economies of poorer countries constructed (usually by a foreign expert) from 1960 onwards. [citation needed] Compared to the Leontief model, development planning models focused more on constraints or shortages—of skilled labour, capital, or foreign exchange.

CGE modelling of richer economies descends from Leif Johansen's 1960[1] MSG model of Norway, and the static model developed by the Cambridge Growth Project in the UK. Both models were pragmatic in flavour, and traced variables through time. The Australian MONASH model[2] is a modern representative of this class. Perhaps the first CGE model similar to those of today was that of Taylor and Black (1974). [3]

CGE models are useful whenever we wish to estimate the effect of changes in one part of the economy upon the rest. For example, a tax on flour might affect bread prices, the CPI, and hence perhaps wages and employment. They have been used widely to analyse trade policy. More recently, CGE has been a popular way to estimate the economic effects of measures to reduce greenhouse gas emissions.

CGE models always contain more variables than equations—so some variables must be set outside the model. These variables are termed exogenous; the remainder, determined by the model, are called endogenous. The choice of which variables are to be exogenous is called the model closure, and may give rise to controversy. For example, some modellers hold employment and the trade balance fixed; others allow these to vary. Variables defining technology, consumer tastes, and government instruments (such as tax rates) are usually exogenous.

Today there are many CGE models of different countries. One of the most well-known CGE models is global: the GTAP[4] model of world trade.

CGE models are useful to model the economies of countries for which time series data are scarce or not relevant (perhaps because of disturbances such as regime changes). Here, strong, reasonable, assumptions embedded in the model must replace historical evidence. Thus developing economies are often analysed using CGE models, such as those based on the IFPRI template model.[5]

Comparative-static and dynamic CGE models

Many CGE models are comparative-static: they model the reactions of the economy at only one point in time. For policy analysis, results from such a model are often interpreted as showing the reaction of the economy in some future period to one or a few external shocks or policy changes. That is, the results show the difference (usually reported in percent change form) between two alternative future states (with and without the policy shock). The process of adjustment to the new equilibrium is not explicitly represented in such a model, although details of the closure (for example, whether capital stocks are allowed to adjust) lead modellers to distinguish between short-run and long-run equilibria.

By contrast, dynamic CGE models explicitly trace each variable through time—often at annual intervals. These models are more realistic, but more challenging to construct and solve—they require for instance that future changes are predicted for all exogenous variables, not just those affected by a possible policy change. The dynamic elements may arise from partial adjustment processes or from stock/flow accumulation relations: between capital stocks and investment, and between foreign debt and trade deficits. However there is a potential consistency problem because the variables that change from one equilibrium solution to the next are not necessarily consistent with each other during the period of change.

Recursive-dynamic CGE models are those that can be solved sequentially (one period at a time). They assume that behaviour depends only on current and past states of the economy. Alternatively, if agents' expectations depend on the future state of the economy, it becomes necessary to solve for all periods simultaneously, leading to full multi-period dynamic CGE models. Within the latter group dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models explicitly incorporate uncertainty about the future.

Solution Techniques

Early CGE models were often solved by a program custom-written for that particular model. Models were expensive to construct, and sometimes appeared as a 'black box' to outsiders. Today most CGE models are formulated and solved using one of the GAMS or GEMPACK software systems. AMPL,[6] Excel and MATLAB are also used. Use of such systems has lowered the cost of entry to CGE modelling; allowed model simulations to be independently replicated; and increased the transparency of the models.

See also

References

  1. Johansen, Leif (1960). A Multi-Sectoral Study of Economic Growth, North-Holland (2nd enlarged edition 1974).
  2. Dixon, Peter and Maureen Rimmer (2002). Dynamic General Equilibrium Modelling for Forecasting and Policy: a Practical Guide and Documentation of MONASH, North Holland.
  3. Taylor, L. and S.L. Black (1974), “Practical General Equilibrium Estimation of Resources Pulls under Trade Liberalization”, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 4(1), April, pp. 37-58.
  4. Hertel, Tom (ed.) (1997). Global Trade Analysis: Modeling and Applications, Cambridge University Press.
  5. Löfgren, Hans, Rebecca Lee Harris and Sherman Robinson (2002). A standard Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) in GAMS, Microcomputers in Policy Research, vol.5, International Food Policy Research Institute.
  6. "The Simplest CGE". Retrieved 2011-05-23. 

Further reading

  • Adelman, Irma and Sherman Robinson (1978). Income Distribution Policy in Developing Countries: A Case Study of Korea, Stanford University Press
  • Bouët, Antoine (2008). The Expected Benefits of Trade Liberalization for World Income and Development: Opening the "Black Box" of Global Trade Modeling
  • Cardenete, M. Alejandro, Guerra, Ana-Isabel and Sancho, Ferran (2012). Applied General Equilibrium: An Introduction. Springer.
  • Dervis, Kemal, Jaime de Melo and Sherman Robinson (1982). General Equilibrium Models for Development Policy. Cambridge University Press.
  • Dixon, Peter, Brian Parmenter, John Sutton and Dave Vincent (1982). ORANI: A multisectoral model of the Australian Economy, North-Holland.
  • Dixon, Peter, Brian Parmenter, Alan Powell and Peter Wilcoxen (1992). Notes and Problems in Applied General Equilibrium Economics, North Holland.
  • Dixon, Peter (2006). Evidence-based Trade Policy Decision Making in Australia and the Development of Computable General Equilibrium Modelling, CoPS/IMPACT Working Paper Number G-163
  • Ginsburgh, Victor and Michiel Keyzer (1997). The Structure of Applied General Equilibrium Models, MIT Press.
  • Kehoe, Patrick J. and Timothy J. Kehoe (1994) "A Primer on Static Applied General Equilibrium Models," Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 18(2) .
  • Kehoe, Timothy J. and Edward C. Prescott (1995) Edited volume on "Applied General Equilibrium," Economic Theory, 6.
  • Mitra-Kahn, Benjamin H., 2008, "Debunking the Myths of Computable General Equilibrium Models", SCEPA Working Paper 01-2008
  • Piermartini, Roberta and Robert Teh (2005). Demystifying Modelling Methods for Trade Policy, Discussion Paper No. 10, World Trade Organization, Geneva.
  • Shoven, John and John Whalley (1984). Applied General-Equilibrium Models of Taxation and International Trade: An Introduction and Survey. Journal of Economic Literature, vol.22(3) 1007-51
  • Shoven, John and John Whalley (1992). Applying General Equilibrium, Cambridge University Press.
  • Thorbecke, Erik and collaborators (1992). Adjustment and Equity in Indonesia, OECD Development Centre, Paris.
  • Dixon, Peter and Dale W. Jorgenson, ed. (2013). Handbook of Computable General Equilibrium Modeling, Vols. 1A and 1B, North Holland, ISBN 978-0-444-59568-3.
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike; additional terms may apply for the media files.