Path dependence

Path dependence explains how the set of decisions one faces for any given circumstance is limited by the decisions one has made in the past, even though past circumstances may no longer be relevant.[1]

In economics and the social sciences path dependence can refer to either outcomes at a single moment in time or to long run equilibria of a process. In common usage, the phrase implies either:

The first usage, (A): "history matters" is trivially true in the explanatory context; everything has causes. And, in these fields, the direct influence of earlier states isn't notable[4] (compare "path dependent" options in finance, where the influence of history can be non standard).

It is the narrow concept, (B), that has the most explanatory force and which is covered in this article.

Contents

Illustration

Consider as an example the Videotape format war; Two mechanisms independent of product quality could explain how VHS achieved dominance over Betamax from a negligible early adoption lead:

An alternative analysis is that VHS was better adapted to market demands (e.g. having a longer recording time). In this interpretation, path dependence had little to do with VHS's success, which would have occurred even if Betamax had established an early lead.[5]

Positive feedback mechanisms like bandwagon and network effects are at the origin of path-dependence. They lead to a reinforcing pattern, in which industries 'tip' towards one or another product design. Uncoordinated standardisation can be observed in many other situations.

Economics

Path dependency theory was originally developed by economists to explain technology adoption processes and industry evolution. The theoretical ideas have had a strong influence on evolutionary economics (e.g., Nelson & Winter 1982).

There are many models and empirical cases where economic processes do not progress steadily toward some pre-determined and unique equilibrium, so that the nature of any equilibrium achieved depends partly on the process of getting there. The outcome of a path dependent process will often not converge towards a unique equilibrium but instead reach one of several equilibria (sometimes known as absorbing states).

This dynamic vision of economic evolution is very different from the neo-classical economics tradition, which in its simplest form assumed that only a single outcome could possibly be reached, regardless of initial conditions or transitory events. With path dependence, both the starting point and 'accidental' events (noise) can have significant effects on the ultimate outcome. In each of the following examples it is possible to identify some random events that disrupted the ongoing course, with irreversible consequences:

Liebowitz and Margolis distinguish types of path dependence;[3] some do not imply inefficiencies and do not challenge the policy implications of neoclassical economics. Only "third degree" path dependence - where switching gains are high but transition is impractical - involves such a challenge. They argue that such situations should be rare for theoretical reasons and that no real-world cases of private locked-in inefficiencies exist.[15] Vergne and Durand qualify this critique by specifying the conditions under which path dependence theory can be tested empirically.[16]

Technically, a path-dependence stochastic process has an asymptotic distribution that "evolves as a consequence (function of) the process's own history".[17] This is also known as a non-ergodic stochastic process.

In The Theory of the Growth of the Firm (1959), Edith Penrose analyzed how the growth of a firm both organically and through acquisition is strongly influenced by the experience of its managers and the history of the firm's development.

History

Recent methodological work in comparative politics and sociology has adapted the concept of path dependence into analyses of political and social phenomena. Path dependence has primarily been used in comparative-historical analyses of the development and persistence of institutions, whether they be social, political, or cultural. There are arguably two types of path-dependent processes:

The critical juncture framework has been used to explain the development and persistence of welfare states, labor incorporation in Latin America, and the variations in economic development between countries, among other things. Scholars such as Kathleen Thelen caution that the historical determinism in path-dependent frameworks is subject to constant disruption from institutional evolution.

Social sciences

An influential attempt to rigorously formalize path dependence within political science is that of Paul Pierson, partly drawing on ideas from economics. Herman Schwartz has questioned those efforts, arguing that forces analogous to those identified in the economic literature are not pervasive in the political realm, where the strategic exercise of power give rise to, and transform institutions.

The path-dependence of emergent strategy has been observed in behavioral experiments with individuals and groups.[19]

Other examples

See also

Notes

  1. ^ Definition from "Our Love Of Sewers: A Lesson in Path Dependence", Dave Praeger, 15 June 2008.
  2. ^ Liebowitz, S; Margolis, Stephen (2000). Encyclopedia of Law and Economics. p. 981. ISBN 978-1858989846. "Most generally, path dependence means that where we go next depends not only on where we are now, but also upon where we have been." 
  3. ^ a b Liebowitz, S; Margolis, S (September 2000). Bouckaert, Boudewijn; De Geest, Gerrit. eds. Encyclopedia of Law and Economics, Volume I. The History and Methodology of Law and Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. p. 985. ISBN 978-1858989846. http://encyclo.findlaw.com/0770book.pdf. Retrieved 2010-05-20. "path dependence can be weak (the efficiency of the chosen path is tied with some alternatives), semi strong, (the chosen path is not the best but not worth fixing, or strong (the chosen path is highly inefficient, but we are unable to correct it)." 
  4. ^ Bellaïche, Joël. "On the path-dependence of economic growth". Journal of Mathematical Economics 46 (2): 178. http://www.math.columbia.edu/~jbellaic/growth.pdf.  The standard economic growth rate measurements are path dependent, and "the phenomenon of dependence of history might be ignored for short period of time (10 years, 20 years), but is not negligible for secular comparisons."
  5. ^ Liebowitz, Stan (2002). Re-thinking the Network Economy. p. 41. ISBN 978-0814406496. http://www.utdallas.edu/~liebowit/book/chapter1.html#_Toc536617.  It was the inferior playing time that led to the demise of the Betamax, not the fact that it was first or second or third.
  6. ^ Stack, Martin; Gartland, Myles (2003). "Path Creation, Path Dependency, and Alternative Theories of the Firm". Journal of Economic Issues 37 (2): 487.  "Paul David and Brian Arthur published several papers that are now regarded as the foundation of path dependency (David 1985; Arthur 1989, 1990)."
  7. ^ Paul David (1985). "Clio and the Economics of QWERTY". American Economic Review: 332.  In such circumstances "historical accidents" can neither be ignored, nor neatly quarantined for the purpose of economic analysis
  8. ^ Jared Diamond (1997). "The Curse of QWERTY". Discover Magazine. http://discovermagazine.com/1997/apr/thecurseofqwerty1099. 
  9. ^ Liebowitz, S.J.; Margolis, S.E. (April 1990). "we conclude that QWERTY is about as good a design as any alternative" "The Fable of the Keys". Journal of Law & Economics (Blackwell Publishers) 30: 1–26. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/Delivery.cfm/SSRN_ID1069950_code59984.pdf?abstractid=1069950&mirid=1 "we conclude that QWERTY is about as good a design as any alternative". 
  10. ^ David, Paul A. (1999), "At Last, a Remedy for Chronic QWERTY-skepticism!", paper for the European Summer School in Industrial Dynamics (ESSID) at l’Institute d’Etudes Scientifique de Cargèse (Corse), France, 5–12 September 1999.
  11. ^ Douglas Puffert (2008-02-10). "Path Dependence". http://eh.net/encyclopedia/article/puffert.path.dependence. Retrieved 20 May 2010. 
  12. ^ D'Souza, Raissa M., et al., (2007) "Emergence of Tempered Preferential Attachment From Optimization", Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 104(15):6112-6117
  13. ^ Jennen, M; Verwijmeren, P (2009). "Agglomeration Effects and Financial Performance". Urban Studies. SSRN 1009226. 
  14. ^ Global Networks and Local Linkages: The Paradox of Cluster Development in an Open Economy. Montreal and Kingston: McGill-Queens University Press for Queen’s School of Policy Studies. 2005. p. 230. ISBN 978-1553390473. http://www.druid.dk/uploads/tx_picturedb/dw2005-1650.pdf. Retrieved 2010-05-20. 
  15. ^ Stephen E. Margolis & S. J. Liebowitz. "Path Dependence 4. Evidence for Third- Degree Path Dependence". http://www.utdallas.edu/~liebowit/palgrave/palpd.html. Retrieved 20 May 2010.  "Our reading of the evidence is that there are as yet no proven examples of third degree path dependence in markets."
  16. ^ JP Vergne & R Durand. The missing link between the theory and empirics of path dependence. doi:10.1111/j.1467-6486.2009.00913.x.  "In particular, we suggest moving away from historical case studies of supposedly path-dependent processes to focus on more controlled research designs such as simulations, experiments, and counterfactual investigation."
  17. ^ David, Paul (2005). Evolution and path dependence in economic ideas: past and present. Edward Elgar. p. 19. ISBN 978-1840640816. "as generally is the case for branching processes [in Path dependence, its critics and the quest for 'historical economics']" 
  18. ^ Page, S (2006). "Path Dependence". Quarterly Journal of Political Science 1: 88. doi:10.1561/100.00000006. http://dev.wcfia.harvard.edu/sites/default/files/Page2006.pdf. 
  19. ^ Egidi, Massimo; Narduzzo, Alessandro (October 1997). "The emergence of path-dependent behaviors in cooperative contexts". International Journal of Industrial Organization 15 (6): 677. doi:10.1016/S0167-7187(97)00007-6. http://www-ceel.economia.unitn.it/papers/lyon.html.  "[Some test subjects] adopted a strategy once and for all and insisted on using it even when the configurations could not be efficiently played with the strategy adopted."

References