Economics of global warming

This article describes the economics of global warming and climate change.

Contents

Definitions

In this article, the phrase “climate change” is used to describe a change in the climate, measured in terms of its statistical properties, e.g., the global mean surface temperature.[1] In this context, “climate” is taken to mean the average weather. Climate can change over period of time ranging from months to thousands or millions of years. The classical time period is 30 years, as defined by the World Meteorological Organization. The climate change referred to may be due to natural causes, e.g., changes in the sun's output, or due to human activities, e.g., changing the composition of the atmosphere.[2] Any human-induced changes in climate will occur against the “background” of natural climatic variations (see attribution of recent climate change for more information).

In this article, the phrase “global warming” refers to the change in the Earth's global average surface temperature.[3] Measurements show a global temperature increase of 1.4 °F (0.78 °C) between the years 1900 and 2005. Global warming is closely associated with a broad spectrum of other climate changes, such as increases in the frequency of intense rainfall, decreases in snow cover and sea ice, more frequent and intense heat waves, rising sea levels, and widespread ocean acidification.[4]

Climate change science

This section describes the science of climate change in relation to economics (Munasinghe et al., 1995:39-41):[5]

Scenarios

Socioeconomic scenarios are used by analysts to make projections of future GHG emissions and to assess future vulnerability to climate change (Carter et al., 2001:151).[7] Producing scenarios requires estimates of future population levels, economic activity, the structure of governance, social values, and patterns of technological change. Economic and energy modelling (such as via the World3 or the POLES models) can be used to analyse and quantify the effects of such drivers.

Emissions scenarios

One type of emissions scenario is called a "global future" scenario. These scenarios can be thought of as stories of possible futures. They allow the description of factors that are difficult to quantify, such as governance, social structures, and institutions. Morita et al. (2001:137-142) assessed the literature on global futures scenarios.[8] They found considerable variety among scenarios, ranging from variants of sustainable development, to the collapse of social, economic, and environmental systems.

No strong patterns were found in the relationship between economic activity and GHG emissions. Economic growth was found to be compatible with increasing or decreasing GHG emissions. In the latter case, emissions growth is mediated by increased energy efficiency, shifts to non-fossil energy sources, and/or shifts to a post-industrial (service-based) economy.

Factors affecting emissions growth

Trends and projections

Emissions

The Kaya identity expresses the level of energy related CO2 emissions as the product of four indicators (Rogner et al., 2007, p. 107):[10]

GDP/capita growth (an aspect of economic development) and population growth were the main drivers of the increase in global emissions during the last three decades of the 20th century. At the global scale, declining carbon and energy intensities have been unable to offset these effects, and consequently, carbon emissions have risen.

Equity and GHG emissions

There are a number of issues relating to equity and GHG emissions (equity is the concept of fairness in economics). For example, a persistent theme in the scientific literature is the explicit or implicit assignment of responsibility for global warming trends (Banuri et al., 2001[11]  ; see also Banuri et al. (1996:91)[12] for a discussion of this issue). Examples of emissions allocation include a country's annual emissions, national annual emissions divided by population (per capita emissions), and emissions per unit of income.[11] Emissions may also be measured over longer time periods (historical or cumulative emissions) (Banuri et al., 1996:91).[12] Some of these different types of measurement are described in greenhouse gas#Regional and national attribution of emissions. It is also possible to make estimates of who has contributed most to changes in global average temperature (i.e., global warming), but there are uncertainties in making such estimates.[11] However, most estimates assessed by Banuri et al. (2001)[11] suggested that developing countries might overtake developed countries in terms of the total contribution to global warming by the years 2060 to 2090. Developed countries' past contributions to climate change were in the process of economically developing to their current level of prosperity; developing countries are attempting to rise to this level, this being one cause of their increasing greenhouse gas emissions.[13]

Another aspect of equity in regards to emissions is that of GHG scenarios.[11] For example, the scenarios used in the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change's (IPCC) First Assessment Report of 1990 were criticized for embodying what the critics considered highly inequitable assumptions, both in the reference scenario (i.e., a scenario which assumes no future efforts to curb emissions) and in the apportioning of emissions reductions in emissions abatement scenarios (Banuri et al., 1996:95).[12] The IPCC's later "SRES" scenarios, published in 2000, explicitly explore scenarios with a narrowing income gap (convergence) between the developed and developing countries.[11] Projections of convergence in the SRES scenarios have been criticized for lacking objectivity (Defra/HM Treasury, 2005;[14] see also Tol (2005) for a discussion).[15]

Emissions projections

Without additional policies to cut GHG emissions (including efforts to reduce deforestation), they are projected to increase between 25% and 90% by 2030 relative to their 2000 levels (Rogner et al., 2007:111). Two-thirds to three-quarters of the increase in CO2 emissions are projected to come from developing countries, although the average per capita CO2 emissions in developing country regions will remain substantially lower than those in developed country regions.

By 2100, projections range from a 40% reduction to an increase in emissions of 250% above their levels in 2000. Atmospheric concentrations of GHGs (see below) are unlikely to stabilize this century without major policy changes.

Concentrations

Rogner et al. (2007:102) reported that the then-current estimated total atmospheric concentration of long-lived GHGs was around 455 parts-per-million (ppm) CO2-eq (range: 433-477 ppm CO2-eq). The effects of aerosol and land-use change changes reduced the physical effect (the radiative forcing) of this to 311 to 435 ppm CO2-eq, with a central estimate of about 375 ppm CO2-eq.

Cost-benefit analysis

Standard cost-benefit analysis can be applied to the problem of climate change (Goldemberg et al., 1996:24,31-32).[17] This requires (1) the valuation of costs and benefits using the willingness to pay as a measure of value, and (2) a criterion for accepting or rejecting proposals:

(1) The valuation of costs and benefits of climate change is difficult because some climate change impacts are difficult to assign a value to, e.g., ecosystems and human health. It is also impossible to know the preferences of future generations, which affects the valuation of costs and benefits (DeCanio, 2007:4).[18]

(2) The standard criterion is the compensation principle. According to the compensation principle, so long as those benefitting from a particular project compensate the losers, and there is still something left over, then the result is an unambiguous gain in welfare. If there are no mechanisms allowing compensation to be paid, then it is necessary to assign weights to particular individuals.

One of the mechanisms for compensation is impossible for this problem: mitigation might benefit future generations at the expense of current generations, but there is no way that future generations can compensate current generations for the costs of mitigation (DeCanio, 2007:4). On the other hand, should future generations bear most of the costs of climate change, compensation to them would not be possible (Goldemberg et al., 1996:32). Another transfer for compensation exists between regions and populations. If, for example, some countries were to benefit from future climate change but others lose out, there is no guarantee that the winners would compensate the losers; similarly, if some countries were to benefit from reducing climate change but others lose out, there would likewise be no guarantee that the winners would compensate the losers.

Risk

In a cost-benefit analysis, an acceptable risk means that the benefits of a climate policy outweigh the costs of the policy (Halsnæs et al., 2007).[19] The standard rule used by public and private decision makers is that a risk will be acceptable if the expected net present value is positive. The expected value is the mean of the distribution of expected outcomes (Goldemberg et al., 1996, p. 25).[17] In other words, it is the average expected outcome for a particular decision. This criterion has been justified on the basis that:

On the first point, probabilities for climate change are difficult to calculate. Also, some impacts, such as those on human health and biodiversity, are difficult to value. On the second point, it has been suggested that insurance could be bought against climate change risks. In practice, however, there are difficulties in implementing the necessary policies to diversify climate change risks.

Risk

One of the problems of climate change are the large uncertainties over the potential impacts of climate change, and the costs and benefits of actions taken in response to climate change, e.g., in reducing GHG emissions (Toth et al., 2001, p. 608).[20] Two related ways of thinking about the problem of climate change decision-making in the presence of uncertainty are iterative risk management (Fisher et al., 2007;[21] Yohe, 2010)[22] and sequential decision making (Toth et al., 2001).[23] Considerations in a risk-based approach might include, for example, the potential for low-probability, worst-case climate change impacts (Barker et al., 2007a).[24]

An approach based on sequential decision making recognises that, over time, decisions related to climate change can be revised in the light of improved information (Goldemberg et al., 1996, p. 26).[17] This is particularly important with respect to climate change, due to the long-term nature of the problem. A near-term hedging strategy concerned with reducing future climate impacts might favour stringent, near-term emissions reductions (Toth et al., 2001, pp. 612–613).[25] Such an approach would allow for greater future flexibility with regard to a low stabilization target, e.g., 450 ppmv CO2. To put it differently, stringent near-term emissions abatement can be seen as having an option value in allowing for lower, long-term stabilization targets. This option may be lost if near-term emissions abatement is less stringent.

On the other hand, a view may be taken that points to the benefits of improved information over time. This may suggest an approach where near-term emissions abatement is more modest (Defra/HM Treasury, 2005).[26] Another way of viewing the problem is to look at the potential irreversibility of future climate change impacts (e.g., damages to ecosystems) against the irreversibility of making investments in efforts to reduce emissions (Goldemberg et al., 1996, p. 26; see also Economics of climate change mitigation#Irreversible impacts and policy).

Resilient and adaptive strategies

CCSP (2009, p. 59) suggested two related decision-making management strategies that might be particularly appealing when faced with high uncertainty.[27] The first were resilient strategies. This seeks to identify a range of possible future circumstances, and then choose approaches that work reasonably well across all the range. The second were adaptive strategies. The idea here is to choose strategies that can be improved as more is learned as the future progresses. CCSP (2009) contrasted these two approaches with the cost-benefit approach, which seeks to find an optimal strategy.

Portfolio theory

An example of a strategy that is based on risk is portfolio theory. This suggests that a reasonable response to uncertainty is to have a wide portfolio of possible responses. In the case of climate change, mitigation can be viewed as an effort to reduce the chance of climate change impacts (Goldemberg et al., 1996, p. 24).[17] Adaptation acts as insurance against the chance that unfavourable impacts occur. The risk associated with these impacts can also be spread. As part of a policy portfolio, climate research can help when making future decisions. Technology research can help to lower future costs.

Optimal choices and risk aversion

The optimal result of decision analysis depends on what criterion is chosen to define what "optimal" is (Arrow et al., 1996, pp. 62–63. See also the section on trade offs).[28] In a decision analysis based on cost-benefit analysis, the optimal policy is evaluated in economic terms. The optimal result of cost-benefit analysis maximizes net benefits. Another type of decision analysis is cost-effectiveness analysis. This is similar to cost-benefit analysis, except that the assessed benefit, or policy target, is set outside of the analysis.

The actual choice of a criterion for deciding the optimal result of decision analysis is a subjective decision. The choice of criterion is made outside of the analysis. One of the influences on this choice on this is attitude to risk. Risk aversion describes how willing or unwilling someone is to take risks. Evidence indicates that most, but not all, individuals prefer certain outcomes to uncertain ones. Risk-averse individuals prefer decision criteria that reduce the chance of the worst possible outcome, while risk-seeking individuals prefer decision criteria that maximize the chance of the best possible outcome. In terms of returns on investment, if society as a whole is risk-averse, we might be willing to accept some investments with negative expected returns, e.g., in mitigation (Goldemberg et al., 1996, p. 24).[17] Such investments may help to reduce the possibility of future climate damages or the costs of adaptation.

International insurance

Traditional insurance works by transferring risk to those better able or more willing to bear risk, and also by the pooling of risk (Goldemberg et al., 1996, p. 25).[17] Since the risks of climate change are, to some extent, correlated, this reduces the effectiveness of pooling. However, there is reason to believe that different regions will be affected differently by climate change. This suggests that pooling might be effective. Since developing countries appear to be potentially most at risk from the effects of climate change, developed countries could provide insurance against these risks.

Authors have pointed to several reasons why commercial insurance markets cannot adequately cover risks associated with climate change (Arrow et al., 1996, p. 72).[28] For example, there is no international market where individuals or countries can insure themselves against losses from climate change or related climate change policies.

Financial markets for risk

There are several options for how insurance could be used in responding to climate change (Arrow et al., 1996, p. 72).[28] One response could be to have binding agreements between countries. Countries suffering greater-than-average climate-related losses would be assisted by those suffering less-than-average losses. This would be a type of mutual insurance contract. Another approach would be to trade "risk securities" among countries. These securities would amount to betting on particular climate outcomes.

These two approaches would allow for a more efficient distribution of climate change risks. They would also allow for different beliefs over future climate outcomes. For example, it has been suggested that these markets might provide an objective test of the honesty of a particular country's beliefs over climate change. Countries that honestly believe that climate change presents little risk would be more prone to hold securities against these risks.

Impacts

Distribution of impacts

Climate change impacts can be measured as an economic cost (Smith et al., 2001, pp. 936–941).[29] This is particularly well-suited to market impacts, that is impacts that are linked to market transactions and directly affect GDP. Monetary measures of non-market impacts, e.g., impacts on human health and ecosystems, are more difficult to calculate. Other difficulties with impact estimates are listed below:

In a literature assessment, Smith et al. (2001, pp. 957–958) concluded, with medium confidence, that:

With high confidence, it was predicted that with a medium (2-3 °C) to high level of warming (greater than 3 °C), negative impacts would be exacerbated, and net positive impacts would start to decline and eventually turn negative.

Aggregate impacts

Aggregating impacts adds up the total impact of climate change across sectors and/or regions (IPCC, 2007a, p. 76).[30] In producing aggregate impacts, there are a number of difficulties, such as predicting the ability of societies to adapt climate change, and estimating how future economic and social development will progress (Smith et al., 2001, p. 941).[29] It is also necessary for the researcher to make subjective value judgements over the importance of impacts occurring in different economic sectors, in different regions, and at different times.

Smith et al. (2001, p. 958) assessed the literature on the aggregate impacts of climate change. With medium confidence, they concluded that a small increase in global average temperature (up to 2 °C, measured against 1990 levels) would result in an aggregate market sector impact of plus or minus a few percent of world GDP. Smith et al. (2001) found that for a small to medium (2-3 °C) global average temperature increase, some studies predicted small net positive market impacts. Most studies they assessed predicted net damages beyond a medium temperature increase, with further damages for greater (more than 3 °C) temperature rises.

Comparison with SRES projections

IPCC (2001, p. 74) compared their literature assessment of the aggregate market sector impacts of climate change against projections of future increases in global mean temperature.[31] Temperature projections were based on the six illustrative SRES emissions scenarios. Projections for the year 2025 ranged from 0.4 to 1.1 °C. For 2050, projections ranged from 0.8 to 2.6 °C, and for 2100, 1.4 to 5.8 °C. These temperature projections correspond to atmospheric CO2 concentrations of 405-460 ppm for the year 2025, 445-640 ppm for 2050, and 540-970 ppm for 2100.

Adaptation and vulnerability

IPCC (2007a) defined adaptation (to climate change) as "[initiatives] and measures to reduce the vulnerability of natural and human systems against actual or expected climate change effects" (p. 76).[30] Vulnerability (to climate change) was defined as "the degree to which a system is susceptible to, and unable to cope with, adverse effects of climate change, including climate variability and extremes" (p. 89).

Autonomous and planned adaptation

Autonomous adaptation are adaptations that are reactive to climatic stimuli, and are done as a matter of course without the intervention of a public agency. Planned adaptation can be reactive or anticipatory, i.e., undertaken before impacts are apparent. Some studies suggest that human systems have considerable capacity to adapt autonomously (Smit et al., 2001:890).[32] Others point to constraints on autonomous adaptation, such as limited information and access to resources (p. 890). Smit et al. (2001:904) concluded that relying on autonomous adaptation to climate change would result in substantial ecological, social, and economic costs. In their view, these costs could largely be avoided with planned adaptation.

Costs and benefits

A literature assessment by Adger et al. (2007:719) concluded that there was a lack of comprehensive, global cost and benefit estimates for adaptation.[33] Studies were noted that provided cost estimates of adaptation at regional level, e.g., for sea-level rise. A number of adaptation measures were identified as having high benefit-cost ratios.

Adaptive capacity

Adaptive capacity is the ability of a system to adjust to climate change. Smit et al. (2001:895-897) described the determinants of adaptive capacity:[32]

Smit et al. (2001) concluded that:

Enhancing adaptive capacity

Smit et al. (2001:905) concluded that enhanced adaptive capacity would reduce vulnerability to climate change. In their view, activities that enhance adaptive capacity are essentially equivalent to activities that promote sustainable development.[32] These activities include (p. 899):

Goklany (1995) concluded that promoting free trade - e.g., through the removal of international trade barriers - could enhance adaptive capacity and contribute to economic growth.[34]

Regions

With high confidence, Smith et al. (2001:957-958) concluded that developing countries would tend to be more vulnerable to climate change than developed countries.[29] Based on then-current development trends, Smith et al. (2001:940-941) predicted that few developing countries would have the capacity to efficiently adapt to climate change.

Systems and sectors

Mitigation

Mitigation of climate change involves actions that are designed to limit the amount of long-term climate change (Fisher et al., 2007:225).[9] Mitigation may be achieved through the reduction of GHG emissions or through the enhancement of sinks that absorb GHGs, e.g., forests.

International public goods

The atmosphere is an international public good, and GHG emissions are an international externality (Goldemberg et al., 1996:21, 28, 43).[17] A change in the quality of the atmosphere does not affect the welfare of all individuals equally. In other words, some individuals may benefit from climate change, while others may lose out. This uneven distribution of potential climate change impacts, plus the uneven distribution of emissions globally, make it difficult to secure a global agreement to reduce emissions (Halsnæs et al., 2007:127).[46]

Policies

National

Both climate and non-climate policies can affect emissions growth. Non-climate policies that can affect emissions are listed below (Bashmakov et al., 2001:409-410):[47]

There are a number of policies that might be used to mitigate climate change, including (Bashmakov et al., 2001:412-422):

International

Finance

The International Energy Agency estimates that US$197 billion is required by states in the developing world above and beyond the underlying investments needed by various sectors regardless of climate considerations, this is twice the amount promised by the developed world at the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) Cancún Agreements.[51] Thus, a new method is being developed to help ensure that funding is available for climate change mitigation.[51] This involves financial leveraging, whereby public financing is used to encourage private investment.[51]

Cost estimates

According to a literature assessment by Barker et al. (2007b:622), mitigation cost estimates depend critically on the baseline (in this case, a reference scenario that the alternative scenario is compared with), the way costs are modelled, and assumptions about future government policy.[52] Fisher et al. (2007) estimated macroeconomic costs in 2030 for multi-gas mitigation (reducing emissions of carbon dioxide and other GHGs, such as methane) as between a 3% decrease in global GDP to a small increase, relative to baseline.[9] This was for an emissions pathway consistent with atmospheric stabilization of GHGs between 445 and 710 ppm CO2-eq. In 2050, the estimated costs for stabilization between 710 and 445 ppm CO2-eq ranged between a 1% gain to a 5.5% decrease in global GDP, relative to baseline. These cost estimates were supported by a moderate amount of evidence and much agreement in the literature (IPCC, 2007b:11,18).[53]

Macroeconomic cost estimates made by Fisher et al. (2007:204) were mostly based on models that assumed transparent markets, no transaction costs, and perfect implementation of cost-effective policy measures across all regions throughout the 21st century. According to Fisher et al. (2007), relaxation of some or all these assumptions would lead to an appreciable increase in cost estimates. On the other hand, IPCC (2007b:8) noted that cost estimates could be reduced by allowing for accelerated technological learning, or the possible use of carbon tax/emission permit revenues to reform national tax systems.

Adaptation and mitigation

The distribution of benefits from adaptation and mitigation policies are different in terms of damages avoided (Toth et al., 2001:653).[25] Adaptation activities mainly benefit those who implement them, while mitigation benefits others who may not have made mitigation investments. Mitigation can therefore be viewed as a global public good, while adaptation is either a private good in the case of autonomous adaptation, or a national or regional public good in the case of public sector policies.

Paying for an international public good

Economists generally agree on the following two principles (Goldemberg, et al.., 1996:29):[17]

Some early studies suggested that a uniform carbon tax would be a fair and efficient way of reducing emissions (Banuri et al., 1996, pp. 103–104).[12] A carbon tax is a Pigouvian tax, and taxes fuels based on their carbon content (Hoeller and Wallin, 1991, p. 92).[54] A literature assessment by Banuri et al. (1996:103-104)[12] summarized criticisms of such a system:

An alternative approach to having a Pigouvian tax is one based on property rights. A practical example of this would be a system of emissions trading, which is essentially a privatization of the atmosphere (Hepburn, 2007).[58] The idea of using property rights in response to an externality was put forward by Coase (1960). Coase's model of social cost assumes a situation of equal bargaining power among participants and equal costs of making the bargain (Toth et al.., 2001:668).[25] Assigning property rights can be an efficient solution. This is based on the assumption that there are no bargaining/transaction costs involved in buying or selling these property rights, and that buyers and sellers have perfect information available when making their decisions.

If these assumptions are correct, efficiency is achieved regardless of how property rights are allocated. In the case of emissions trading, this suggests that equity and efficiency can be addressed separately: equity is taken care of in the allocation of emission permits, and efficiency is promoted by the market system. In reality, however, markets do not live up to the ideal conditions that are assumed in Coase's model, with the result that there may be trade-offs between efficiency and equity (Halsnæs et al., 2007).[59]

Efficiency and equity

No scientific consensus exists on who should bear the burden of adaptation and mitigation costs (Goldemberg et al.., 1996:29).[17] Several different arguments have been made over how to spread the costs and benefits of taxes or systems based on emissions trading.

One approach considers the problem from the perspective of who benefits most from the public good. This approach is sensitive to the fact that different preferences exist between different income classes. The public good is viewed in a similar way as a private good, where those who use the public good must pay for it. Some people will benefit more from the public good than others, thus creating inequalities in the absence of benefit taxes. A difficulty with public goods is determining who exactly benefits from the public good, although some estimates of the distribution of the costs and benefits of global warming have been made - see above. Additionally, this approach does not provide guidance as to how the surplus of benefits from climate policy should be shared.

A second approach has been suggested based on economics and the social welfare function. To calculate the social welfare function requires an aggregation of the impacts of climate change policies and climate change itself across all affected individuals. This calculation involves a number of complexities and controversial equity issues (Markandya et al., 2001:460).[60] For example, the monetization of certain impacts on human health. There is also controversy over the issue of benefits affecting one individual offsetting negative impacts on another (Smith et al.., 2001:958).[29] These issues to do with equity and aggregation cannot be fully resolved by economics (Banuri et al.., 1996:87).[12]

On a utilitarian basis, which has traditionally been used in welfare economics, an argument can be made for richer countries taking on most of the burdens of mitigation (Halsnæs et al., 2007).[61] However, another result is possible with a different modeling of impacts. If an approach is taken where the interests of poorer people have lower weighting, the result is that there is a much weaker argument in favour of mitigation action in rich countries. Valuing climate change impacts in poorer countries less than domestic climate change impacts (both in terms of policy and the impacts of climate change) would be consistent with observed spending in rich countries on foreign aid (Hepburn, 2005;[62] Helm, 2008:229).[63]

In terms of the social welfare function, the different results depend on the elasticity of marginal utility. A declining marginal utility of consumption means that a poor person is judged to benefit more from increases in consumption relative to a richer person. A constant marginal utility of consumption does not make this distinction, and leads to the result that richer countries should mitigate less.

A third approach looks at the problem from the perspective of who has contributed most to the problem. Because the industrialized countries have contributed more than two-thirds of the stock of human-induced GHGs in the atmosphere, this approach suggests that they should bear the largest share of the costs. This stock of emissions has been described as an "environmental debt" (Munasinghe et al., 1996, p. 167).[64] In terms of efficiency, this view is not supported. This is because efficiency requires incentives to be forward-looking, and not retrospective (Goldemberg et al., 1996, p. 29). The question of historical responsibility is a matter of ethics. Munasinghe et al. (1996, p. 167) suggested that developed countries could address the issue by making side-payments to developing countries.

Trade offs

It is often argued in the literature that there is a trade-off between adaptation and mitigation, in that the resources committed to one are not available for the other (Schneider et al., 2001:94).[65] This is debatable in practice because the people who bear emission reduction costs or benefits are often different from those who pay or benefit from adaptation measures.

There is also a trade off in how much damage from climate change should be avoided. The assumption that it is always possible to trade off different outcomes is viewed as problematic by many people (Halsnæs et al., 2007).[66] For example, a trade off might exist between economic growth and damages faced by indigenous cultures.

Some of the literature has pointed to difficulties in these kinds of assumptions. For instance, there may be aversion at any price towards losing particular species. It has also been suggested that low-probability, extreme outcomes are overweighted when making choices. This is related to climate change, since the possibility of future abrupt changes in the climate or the Earth system cannot be ruled out. For example, if the West Antarctic ice sheet was to disintegrate, it could result in a sea level rise of 4–6 meters over several centuries.

Cost-benefit analysis

In a cost-benefit analysis, the trade offs between climate change impacts, adaptation, and mitigation are made explicit. Cost-benefit analyses of climate change are produced using integrated assessment models (IAMs), which incorporate aspects of the natural, social, and economic sciences.

In an IAM designed for cost-benefit analysis, the costs and benefits of impacts, adaptation and mitigation are converted into monetary estimates. Some view the monetization of costs and benefits as controversial (see Economic impacts of climate change#Aggregate impacts). The "optimal" levels of mitigation and adaptation are then resolved by comparing the marginal costs of action with the marginal benefits of avoided climate change damages (Toth et al., 2001:654).[25] The decision over what "optimal" is depends on subjective value judgements made by the author of the study (Azar, 1998).[67]

There are many uncertainties that affect cost-benefit analysis, for example, sector- and country-specific damage functions (Toth et al., 2001:654). Another example is with adaptation. The options and costs for adaptation are largely unknown, especially in developing countries.

Results

A common finding of cost-benefit analysis is that the optimum level of emissions reduction is modest in the near-term, with more stringent abatement in the longer-term (Stern, 2007:298;[68] Heal, 2008:20;[69] Barker, 2008).[70] This approach might lead to a warming of more than 3 °C above the pre-industrial level (World Bank, 2010:8).[71] In most models, benefits exceed costs for stabilization of GHGs leading to warming of 2.5 °C. No models suggest that the optimal policy is to do nothing, i.e., allow "business-as-usual" emissions.

Along the efficient emission path calculated by Nordhaus and Boyer (2000) (referred to by Fisher et al.., 2007), the long-run global average temperature after 500 years increases by 6.2 °C above the 1900 level.[72] Nordhaus and Boyer (2000) stated their concern over the potentially large and uncertain impacts of such a large environmental change. It should be noted that the projected temperature in this IAM, like any other, is subject to scientific uncertainty (e.g., the relationship between concentrations of GHGs and global mean temperature, which is called the climate sensitivity). Projections of future atmospheric concentrations based on emission pathways are also affected by scientific uncertainties, e.g., over how carbon sinks, such as forests, will be affected by future climate change. Klein et al. (2007) concluded that there were few high quality studies in this area, and placed low confidence in the results of cost-benefit analysis.[73]

Hof et al. (2008) (referred to by World Bank, 2010:8) examined the sensitivity of the optimal climate target to assumptions about the time horizon, climate sensitivity, mitigation costs, likely damages, and discount rates. The optimal target was defined as the concentration that would result in the lowest reduction in the present value (i.e., discounted) of global consumption. A set of assumptions that included a relatively high climate sensitivity (i.e., a relatively large global temperature increase for a given increase in GHGs), high damages, a long time horizon, low discount rates (i.e., future consumption is valued relatively highly), and low mitigation costs, produced an optimum peak in the concentration of CO2e at 540 parts per million (ppm). Another set of assumptions that assumed a lower climate sensitivity (lower global temperature increase), lower damages, a shorter time horizon, and a higher discount rate (present consumption is valued relatively more highly), produced an optimum peaking at 750 ppm.

Strengths

In spite of various uncertainties or possible criticisms of cost-benefit analysis, it does have several strengths:

Geoengineering

Geoengineering are technological efforts to stabilize the climate system by direct intervention in the Earth-atmosphere-system's energy balance (Verbruggen, 2007, p. 815).[75] The intent of geoengineering is to reduce the amount of global warming (the observed trend of increased global average temperature (NRC, 2008, p. 2)).[76] IPCC (2007b:15) concluded that reliable cost estimates for geoengineering options had not been published.[53] This finding was based on medium agreement in the literature and limited evidence.

Major reports considering economics of climate change

The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) has produced several reports where the economics literature on climate change is assessed. In 1995, the IPCC produced its second set of assessment reports on climate change. Working Group III of the IPCC produced a report on the "Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change." In the later third and fourth IPCC assessments, published in 2001 and 2007 respectively, the assessment of the economics literature is divided across two reports produced by IPCC Working Groups II and III.

The Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change is a 700-page report released for the British government on October 30, 2006 by economist Nicholas Stern chair of the Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment at the London School of Economics. The report discusses the effect of global warming on the world economy.

The Garnaut Climate Change Review was a study by Professor Ross Garnaut, commissioned by then Opposition Leader, Kevin Rudd[77] and by the Australian State and Territory Governments on 30 April 2007. After his election on 24 November 2007 Prime Minister of Australia Kevin Rudd confirmed the participation of the Commonwealth Government in the Review.

See also

Global warming portal
Environment portal
Energy portal

References

  1. ^ Baede, A.P.M. (ed) (2007). "Glossary A-D". In Solomon, S., D. Qin, M. Manning, Z. Chen, M. Marquis, K.B. Averyt, M. Tignor and H.L. Miller. Climate Change 2007: Working Group I: The Physical Science Basis. Contribution of Working Group I to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Print version: Printed by Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. Web version: IPCC website. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg1/en/annex1sglossary-a-d.html. 
  2. ^ Albritton, D.L. et al. (2001). "Box 1: What drives changes in climate? In (book section): Technical Summary". In Houghton, J.T. et al.. Climate Change 2001: Working Group I: The Scientific Basis. Contribution of Working Group I to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Print version: Printed by Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. Web version: UNEP/GRID-Arendal website. http://www.grida.no/publications/other/ipcc_tar/. 
  3. ^ NRC (2008). "Understanding and Responding to Climate Change" (PDF). Board on Atmospheric Sciences and Climate, US National Academy of Sciences. p. 4. http://dels.nas.edu/resources/static-assets/materials-based-on-reports/booklets/climate_change_2008_final.pdf. Retrieved 2010-11-09. 
  4. ^ America's Climate Choices: Panel on Advancing the Science of Climate Change; National Research Council (2010). What we know about climate change. In (book section): Summary. In: Advancing the Science of Climate Change (pre-publication edition). The National Academies Press, Washington, D.C.. p. 2. http://books.nap.edu/openbook.php?record_id=12782&page=2. 
  5. ^ Munasinghe, M. et al. (1995). "Applicability of Techniques of Cost-Benefit Analysis to Climate Change". In M. Munasinghe. World Bank Environment Paper Number 12: Global Climate Change: Economic and Policy Issues. The World Bank, Washington, D.C., U.S.A.. http://go.worldbank.org/RBZH3Z1SJ0. Retrieved 2010-02-11. 
  6. ^ US NRC (2001). "Climate Change Science: An Analysis of Some Key Questions". National Academy Press, Washington, D.C., U.S.A.. http://www.nap.edu/openbook.php?record_id=10139. Retrieved 2010-02-11. 
  7. ^ Carter, T.R. et al. (2001). "Developing and Applying Scenarios. In: Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [J.J. McCarthy et al. Eds."]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.htm. Retrieved 2010-01-10. 
  8. ^ a b Morita, T. et al. (2001). "Greenhouse Gas Emission Mitigation Scenarios and Implications. In: Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [B. Metz et al. Eds."]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.htm. Retrieved 2010-01-10. 
  9. ^ a b c Fisher, B.S. et al. (2007). "Issues related to mitigation in the long term context. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [B. Metz et al. Eds."]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.htm. Retrieved 2009-05-20. 
  10. ^ Rogner, H.-H., D. Zhou, R. Bradley. P. Crabbé, O. Edenhofer, B.Hare, L. Kuijpers, M. Yamaguchi (2007). 1.3.1.2 Intensities. In (book chapter): Introduction. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz, O.R. Davidson, P.R. Bosch, R. Dave, L.A. Meyer (eds)). Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, USA. This version: IPCC website. ISBN 9780521880114. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/ch1s1-3-1-2.html. Retrieved 2010-05-05. 
  11. ^ a b c d e f Banuri, T., et al. (2001). Box 1.1 A Numbers Game. In: 1. Setting the Stage: Climate Change and Sustainable Development. In: Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz, et al. (eds)). Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, USA. This version: GRID-Arendal website. ISBN 9780521880114. http://www.grida.no/climate/ipcc_tar/wg3/057.htm. Retrieved 2011-11-19. 
  12. ^ a b c d e f g h Banuri, T. et al. (1996). "Equity and Social Considerations.". In J.P. Bruce et al. (PDF). Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. This version: Printed by Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. Web version: IPCC website. doi:10.2277/0521568544. ISBN 9780521568548. http://www.ipcc.ch/ipccreports/sar/wg_III/ipcc_sar_wg_III_full_report.pdf. 
  13. ^ Sonali P. Chitre (4 April 2011). "India's Role in an International Legal Solution to the Global Climate Change Problem". SSRN. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1802862. Retrieved 20 November 2011. 
  14. ^ Defra/HM Treasury (February 2005). Memorandum by Defra/HM Treasury, paragraph 9. In (section): Select Committee on Economic Affairs Minutes of Evidence. In (report): The Economics of Climate Change, the Second Report of the 2005-2006 session, produced by the UK Parliament House of Lords Economics Affairs Select Committee. UK Parliament website. http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld200506/ldselect/ldeconaf/12/5030104.htm. Retrieved 2011-03-27. 
  15. ^ Tol, R.S.J. (15 January 2005). "Memorandum by Professor Richard S J Tol, Hamburg, Vrije and Carnegie Mellon Universities. In (section): Select Committee on Economic Affairs Minutes of Evidence. In (report): The Economics of Climate Change, the Second Report of the 2005-2006 session, produced by the UK Parliament House of Lords Economics Affairs Select Committee". UK Parliament website. http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld200506/ldselect/ldeconaf/12/5020107.htm. Retrieved 2011-03-27. 
  16. ^ IPCC (2001). "Summary for Policymakers. In: Climate Change 2001: Synthesis Report. A Contribution of Working Groups I, II, and III to the Third Assessment Report of the Integovernmental Panel on Climate Change [Watson, R.T. and the Core Writing Team (eds.)"]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.htm. Retrieved 2009-05-20. 
  17. ^ a b c d e f g h i Goldemberg, J. et al. (1996). "Introduction: scope of the assessment.". In J.P. Bruce et al. (PDF). Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. This version: Printed by Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. Web version: IPCC website. doi:10.2277/0521568544. ISBN 9780521568548. http://www.ipcc.ch/ipccreports/sar/wg_III/ipcc_sar_wg_III_full_report.pdf. 
  18. ^ DeCanio, S.J. (October 17, 2007). "Reflections on Climate Change, Economic Development, and Global Equity". The website of Stephen J. DeCanio, Professor of Economics, Emeritus, at the University of California, Santa Barbara. http://www.stephendecanio.com/Stephen_DeCanio_Site/DeCanioLeontief07-1.pdf. Retrieved 2010-02-20. 
  19. ^ Halsnæs, K. et al. (2007). "2.3.3 Costs, benefits and uncertainties. Framing issues". In B. Metz et al.. Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. ISBN 9780521880114. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/ch2s2-3-3.html. Retrieved 2010-05-23. 
  20. ^ Toth et al., 2001. 10.1.2.4 Uncertainty Is Pervasive
  21. ^ Fisher, B.S., N. Nakicenovic, K. Alfsen, J. Corfee Morlot, F. de la Chesnaye, J.-Ch. Hourcade, K. Jiang, M. Kainuma, E. La Rovere, A. Matysek, A. Rana, K. Riahi, R. Richels, S. Rose, D. van Vuuren, R. Warren (2007). 3.5.1.1 An iterative risk-management framework to articulate options. In: Chapter 3: Issues related to mitigation in the long-term context. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz, O.R. Davidson, P.R. Bosch, R. Dave, L.A. Meyer (eds)). Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, USA. This version: IPCC website. ISBN 9780521880114. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/ch3s3-5-1-1.html. Retrieved 2010-05-25. 
  22. ^ Yohe, G.W. (May 2010). "Addressing Climate Change through a Risk Management Lens. In: Assessing the Benefits of Avoided Climate Change: Cost-Benefit Analysis and Beyond. (Gulledge, J., L. J. Richardson, L. Adkins, and S. Seidel (eds.)), Proceedings of Workshop on Assessing the Benefits of Avoided Climate Change, March 16–17, 2009. Pew Center on Global Climate Change: Arlington, VA". Pew Center on Global Climate Change. pp. 201–231. http://www.pewclimate.org/events/2009/benefitsworkshop. Retrieved 2010-05-25. 
  23. ^ Toth et al., 2001. 10.1.4.1 Decision Making under Uncertainty
  24. ^ Barker T., I. Bashmakov, L. Bernstein, J. E. Bogner, P. R. Bosch, R. Dave, O. R. Davidson, B. S. Fisher, S. Gupta, K. Halsnæs, G.J. Heij, S. Kahn Ribeiro, S. Kobayashi, M. D. Levine, D. L. Martino, O. Masera, B. Metz, L. A. Meyer, G.-J. Nabuurs, A. Najam, N. Nakicenovic, H. -H. Rogner, J. Roy, J. Sathaye, R. Schock, P. Shukla, R. E. H. Sims, P. Smith, D. A. Tirpak, D. Urge-Vorsatz, D. Zhou (2007a). Article 2 of the Convention and mitigation. In: Technical summary. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz, O.R. Davidson, P.R. Bosch, R. Dave, L.A. Meyer (eds)). Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, USA. This version: IPCC website. ISBN 9780521880114. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/tssts-ts-1-3-article-2.html. Retrieved 2010-05-25. 
  25. ^ a b c d Toth, F.L. et al. (2001). "Decision-making Frameworks. In: Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change". In B. Metz et al. (Eds.). Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.htm. Retrieved 2010-01-10. 
  26. ^ Defra/HM Treasury (21 June 2005). "Minutes of Evidence, Annex 3. In: Session 2005-2006, Second Report, “The Economics of Climate Change.” Produced by the UK Parliament House of Lords Economics Affairs Select Committee". UK Parliament website. http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld200506/ldselect/ldeconaf/12/5030107.htm. Retrieved 2011-03-27. 
  27. ^ CCSP (January 2009). "Best practice approaches for characterizing, communicating, and incorporating scientific uncertainty in decisionmaking. A Report by the U.S. Climate Change Science Program and the Subcommittee on Global Change Research (Granger Morgan, H. Dowlatabadi, M. Henrion, D. Keith, R. Lempert, S. McBride, M. Small, T. Wilbanks (eds.))". National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration, Washington D.C., USA, via U.S. Global Change Research Program. http://www.globalchange.gov/publications/reports/scientific-assessments/saps/311. Retrieved 2010-05-25. 
  28. ^ a b c Arrow, K.J. et al. (1996) (PDF). Decision-making frameworks for addressing climate change. In: Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J.P. Bruce et al. (eds.)). This version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. Web version: IPCC website. doi:10.2277/0521568544. ISBN 9780521568548. http://www.ipcc.ch/ipccreports/sar/wg_III/ipcc_sar_wg_III_full_report.pdf. 
  29. ^ a b c d e Smith, J.B., et al. (2001). "Vulnerability to Climate Change and Reasons for Concern: A Synthesis. In: Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J.J. McCarthy et al. Eds.)". Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.htm. Retrieved 2010-01-10. 
  30. ^ a b IPCC (2007a). "Climate Change 2007: Synthesis Report. Contribution of Working Groups I, II and III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (Core Writing Team, Pachauri, R.K and Reisinger, A. (eds.))". IPCC, Geneva, Switzerland. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_ipcc_fourth_assessment_report_synthesis_report.htm. Retrieved 2009-05-20. 
  31. ^ IPCC (2001). "Table 3-5. In (section): Question 3". In Watson, R.T. and the Core Writing Team. Climate Change 2001: Synthesis Report. A Contribution of Working Groups I, II, and III to the Third Assessment Report of the Integovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Print version: Cambridge University Press, UK. This version: GRID-Arendal website. p. 74. http://www.grida.no/climate/ipcc_tar/vol4/english/026.htm. Retrieved 2011-03-29. 
  32. ^ a b c Smit, B. et al. (2001). "Adaptation to Climate Change in the Context of Sustainable Development and Equity. In: Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [J.J. McCarthy et al. Eds."]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.htm. Retrieved 2010-01-10. 
  33. ^ Adger, W.N. et al. (2007). "Assessment of adaptation practices, options, constraints and capacity. In: Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [M.L. Parry et al. Eds."]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_ipcc_fourth_assessment_report_wg2_report_impacts_adaptation_and_vulnerability.htm. Retrieved 2009-05-20. 
  34. ^ Goklany, I.M. (1995). "Strategies to enhance adaptability: technological change, sustainable growth and free trade". Climatic Change 30 (4): 427–449. doi:10.1007/BF01093855. http://goklany.org/library/Goklany%201995%20Climatic%20Change.pdf. Retrieved 2010-02-03. 
  35. ^ Boko, M., et al. (2007). "Africa. In: Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change". In M.L. Parry et al. Eds.. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. pp. 433–467. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg2/en/ch9.html. Retrieved 2009-05-20. 
  36. ^ Lal, M. et al. (2001). "Asia. In: Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change". In J.J. McCarthy et al. Eds.. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg2/en/ch10.html. Retrieved 2010-01-10. 
  37. ^ Hennessy, K. et al. (2007). "Australia and New Zealand. In: Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change". In M.L. Parry et al. Eds.. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. pp. 507–540. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg2/en/ch11.html. Retrieved 2009-05-20. 
  38. ^ Kundzewicz, Z.W. et al. (2001). "Europe. In: Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change". In J.J. McCarthy et al. Eds.. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg2/en/ch12.html. Retrieved 2010-01-10. 
  39. ^ Mata, L.J. et al. (2001). "Latin America. In: Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [J.J. McCarthy et al. Eds."]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.htm. Retrieved 2010-01-10. 
  40. ^ Anisimov, O. et al. (2001). Executive Summary. In (book chapter): Polar Regions (Arctic and Antarctic). In: Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J.J. McCarthy et al. (eds.)). Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: GRID-Arendal website. ISBN 0521807689. http://www.grida.no/climate/ipcc_tar/wg2/593.htm. Retrieved 2010-05-23. 
  41. ^ Mimura, N. et al. (2007). Executive summary. In (book chapter): Small islands. In: Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (M.L. Parry et al., (eds.)). Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. ISBN 9780521880107. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg2/en/ch16s16-es.html. Retrieved 2010-05-23. 
  42. ^ Nicholls, R.J. et al. (2007). 6.4.3 Key vulnerabilities and hotspots. In (book chapter): Coastal systems and low-lying areas. In: Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (M.L. Parry et al. (eds.)). Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. ISBN 9780521880107. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg2/en/ch6s6-4-3.html. Retrieved 2010-05-23. 
  43. ^ Nicholls, R.J. et al. (2007). Executive summary. In (book chapter): Coastal systems and low-lying areas. In: Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (M.L. Parry et al. (eds.)). Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. ISBN 9780521880107. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg2/en/ch6s6-es.html. Retrieved 2010-05-23. 
  44. ^ Wilbanks, T.J. et al. (2007). 7.4.1 General effects. In (book chapter): Industry, settlement and society. In: Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (M.L. Parry et al. (eds.)). Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. ISBN 9780521880107. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg2/en/ch7s7-4-1.html. Retrieved 2010-05-23. 
  45. ^ Wilbanks, T.J. et al. (2007). Executive summary. In (book chapter): Industry, settlement and society. In: Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (M.L. Parry et al. (eds.)). Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. ISBN 9780521880107. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg2/en/ch7s7-es.html. Retrieved 2010-05-23. 
  46. ^ Halsnæs, K. et al. (2007). "Framing issues. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [B. Metz et al. Eds."]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.htm. Retrieved 2009-05-20. 
  47. ^ a b Bashmakov, I. et al. (2001). "Policies, Measures, and Instruments. In: Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [B. Metz et al. Eds."]. Cambridge University Press. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.htm. Retrieved 2009-05-20. 
  48. ^ Gupta, S. et al. (2007). "Policies, Instruments and Co-operatuve Arrangements. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [B. Metz et al. Eds."]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.htm. Retrieved 2009-05-20. 
  49. ^ a b Barker, T., et al. (2001). "Sectoral Costs and Ancillary Benefits of Mitigation. In: Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [B. Metz, et al., Eds."]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.htm. Retrieved 2010-01-10. 
  50. ^ Verbruggen, A. (ed) (2007). Glossary J-P. In (book section): Annex I. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz et al. (eds.)). Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. ISBN 9780521880114. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/annex1sglossary-j-p.html. Retrieved 2010-05-23. 
  51. ^ a b c Jessica Brown and Michael Jacobs 2011. Leveraging private investment: the role of public sector climate finance. London: Overseas Development Institute
  52. ^ Barker, T. et al. (2007b). "Mitigation from a cross-sectoral perspective. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [B. Metz et al., Eds."]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.htm. Retrieved 2009-05-20. 
  53. ^ a b IPCC (2007b). "Summary for Policymakers. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [B. Metz et al. Eds."]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.htm. Retrieved 2009-05-20. 
  54. ^ Hoeller, P. and M. Wallin (1991). "OECD Economic Studies No. 17, Autumn 1991. Energy Prices, Taxes and Carbon Dioxide Emissions". OECD website. http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/33/26/34258255.pdf. Retrieved 2010-04-23. 
  55. ^ Banuri, T. et al. (1996). "Equity and Social Considerations.". In J.P. Bruce et al. (PDF). Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. This version: Printed by Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. Web version: IPCC website. p. 104. doi:10.2277/0521568544. ISBN 9780521568548. http://www.ipcc.ch/ipccreports/sar/wg_III/ipcc_sar_wg_III_full_report.pdf. "Even in a scheme involving "equal burdens," most observers argue that a uniform carbon tax would not be fair because of the many differences outlined in Section 3.3 [of the IPCC report], notably differences in historical and current emissions and in current wealth and consequent priorities." 
  56. ^ Chichilnisky, G.; Heal, G. (Spring 1994). "Who should abate carbon emissions? An international viewpoint" (PDF). Economic Letters 44. http://chichilnisky.com/pdfs/papers/93.pdf. Retrieved 2010-05-29. 
  57. ^ Tol, R.S.J. (2001). "Equitable cost-benefit analysis of climate change policies" (PDF). Ecological Economics 36 (1). http://www.mi.uni-hamburg.de/fileadmin/fnu-files/publication/tol/ececequity.pdf. Retrieved 2010-05-29. 
  58. ^ Hepburn, C. (November 2007). "Carbon Trading: A Review of the Kyoto Mechanisms". Annual Review of Environment and Resources 32: 375–393. doi:10.1146/annurev.energy.32.053006.141203. http://arjournals.annualreviews.org/eprint/V5uDHeDwvfmeMnr3IuPZ/full/10.1146/annurev.energy.32.053006.141203. Retrieved 2009-05-20. 
  59. ^ Halsnæs, K. et al. (2007). "2.6.5 Economic efficiency and eventual trade-offs with equity. In (book chapter 2): Framing issues.". In B. Metz et al.. Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/ch2s2-6-5.html. Retrieved 2010-04-06. 
  60. ^ Markandya, A. et al. (2001). "Costing Methodologies.". In B. Metz et al.. Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.htm. Retrieved 2010-01-10. 
  61. ^ Halsnæs, K. et al. (2007). "2.6.4 Equity consequences of different policy instruments, Chapter 2 Framing issues". In B. Metz et al.. Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/ch2s2-6-4.html. Retrieved 2010-04-06. 
  62. ^ Hepburn, C. (28 February 2005). "Memorandum by Dr Cameron Hepburn, St Hugh's College, University of Oxford.". The Economics of Climate Change. Second Report of 2005-2006 Volume II, HL Paper No. 12-II. House of Lords Economic Affairs Select Committee. ISBN 019957328X. http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld200506/ldselect/ldeconaf/12/12we10.htm. Retrieved 2010-04-06. 
  63. ^ Helm, D. (1 November 2008). "Climate-change policy: why has so little been achieved?". Oxford Review of Economic Policy 24 (2): 211–238. doi:10.1093/oxrep/grn014. http://www.dieterhelm.co.uk/node/671. Retrieved 2010-04-06. 
  64. ^ Munasinghe, M. et al. (1996). "Applicability of Techniques of Cost-Benefit Analysis to Climate Change.". In J.P. Bruce et al. (PDF). Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. This version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. Web version: IPCC website. doi:10.2277/0521568544. ISBN 9780521568548. http://www.ipcc.ch/ipccreports/sar/wg_III/ipcc_sar_wg_III_full_report.pdf. 
  65. ^ Schneider, S. et al. (2001). "Overview of Impacts, Adaptation, and Vulnerability to Climate Change. In: Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J.J. McCarthy et al. Eds.)". Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.htm. Retrieved 2010-01-10. 
  66. ^ Halsnæs, K. et al. (2007). 2.2.4 Risk of catastrophic or abrupt change. Framing issues. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz et al. (eds.)). Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. ISBN 9780521880114. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/ch2s2-2-4.html. Retrieved 2010-05-23. 
  67. ^ Azar, C. (1998). "Are Optimal CO2 Emissions Really Optimal? Four Critical Issues for Economists in the Greenhouse". Environmental and Resource Economics 11 (3-4): 301–315. doi:10.1023/A:1008235326513. http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/azar_1998_four_crucial_issues.pdf. Retrieved 2009-01-10. 
  68. ^ Stern, N. (2007). "Towards a Goal for Climate-Change Policy. In: Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change (pre-publication edition)". Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/sternreview_index.htm. Retrieved 2010-02-25. 
  69. ^ Heal, G. (April 2008). "Climate economics: A meta-review and some suggestions. NBER Working Paper 13927". U.S. National Bureau of Economic Research. http://www2.gsb.columbia.edu/faculty/gheal/EnvironmentalEconomicsPapers/NBER%20Climate%20paper%2090198-w13927.pdf. Retrieved 2009-05-20. 
  70. ^ Barker, T. (August 2008). "The economics of avoiding dangerous climate change. An editorial essay on The Stern Review". Climatic Change 89 (3-4): 173–194. doi:10.1007/s10584-008-9433-x. http://www.springerlink.com/content/612k4k5v68r2577m/?p=20cde4d2d12e41939a4faac4082d8512&pi=0. Retrieved 2009-05-20. 
  71. ^ World Bank (2010). "Overview: Changing the Climate for Development. In: World Development Report 2010: Development and Climate Change". The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC 20433. http://go.worldbank.org/BKLQ9DSDU0. Retrieved 2010-04-06. 
  72. ^ Fisher, B.S. et al. (2007). "3.5.3.3 Cost-benefit analysis, damage cost estimates and social costs of carbon. In (book chapter): Issues related to mitigation in the long term context. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz et al. Eds.)". Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/ch3s3-5-3-3.html. Retrieved 2010-04-06. 
  73. ^ Klein, R.J.T. et al. (2007). "18.4.2 Consideration of costs and damages avoided and/or benefits gained. In (book chapter): Inter-relationships between adaptation and mitigation. In: Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (M.L. Parry et al. Eds.)". Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg2/en/ch18s18-4-2.html. Retrieved 2010-04-06. 
  74. ^ Downing, T.E. et al. (2001). "Methods and Tools. In: Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [J.J. McCarthy et al. Eds."]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.htm. Retrieved 2010-01-10. 
  75. ^ Verbruggen, A. (ed) (2007). Glossary E-I. In (book section): Annex I. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz et al. (eds.)). Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. ISBN 9780521880114. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/ar4/wg3/en/annex1sglossary-e-i.html. Retrieved 2010-05-23. 
  76. ^ NRC (2008). "Understanding and Responding to Climate Change". US National Academy of Sciences. http://dels.nas.edu/resources/static-assets/materials-based-on-reports/booklets/climate_change_2008_final.pdf. Retrieved 2010-11-09. 
  77. ^ Garnaut Climate Change Review Draft Report (PDF)

Further reading

External links

Videos