Auction

An auction is a process of buying and selling goods or services by offering them up for bid, taking bids, and then selling the item to the highest bidder. In economic theory, an auction may refer to any mechanism or set of trading rules for exchange.

Contents

History of the auction

The word "auction" is derived from the Latin augeō which means "I increase" or "I augment".[4]

For most of history, auctions have been a relatively uncommon way to negotiate the exchange of goods and commodities. In practice, both haggling and sale by set-price have been significantly more common.[5] Indeed, prior to the seventeenth century the few auctions that were held were sporadic and infrequent.[6]

Nonetheless, auctions have a long history, having been recorded as early as 500 B.C.[7] According to Herodotus, in Babylon auctions of women for marriage were held annually. The auctions began with the woman the auctioneer considered to be the most beautiful and progressed to the least. It was considered illegal to allow a daughter to be sold outside of the auction method.[6]

During the Roman Empire, following military victory, Roman soldiers would often drive a spear into the ground around which the spoils of war were left, to be auctioned off. Later slaves, often captured as the "spoils of war", were auctioned in the forum under the sign of the spear, with the proceeds of sale going towards the war effort.[6]

The Romans also used auctions to liquidate the assets of debtors whose property had been confiscated.[8] For example, Marcus Aurelius sold household furniture to pay off debts, the sales lasting for months.[9] One of the most significant historical auctions occurred in the year 193 A.D. when the entire Roman Empire was put on the auction block by the Praetorian Guard. On March 23 The Praetorian Guard first killed emperor Pertinax, then offered the empire to the highest bidder. Didius Julianus outbid everyone else for the price of 6,250 drachmas per Guard, an act that initiated a brief civil war. Didius was then beheaded two months later when Septimius Severus conquered Rome.[8]

From the end of the Roman Empire to the eighteenth century auctions lost favor in Europe,[8] while they had never been widespread in Asia.[6]

In some parts of England during the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries auction by candle was used for the sale of goods and leaseholds. This auction began by lighting a candle after which bids were offered in ascending order until the candle spluttered out. The high bid at the time the candle extinguished itself won the auction.[10]

The oldest auction house in the world is Stockholm Auction House (Stockholms Auktionsverk). It was established in Sweden in 1674.[11][12]

During the end of the 18th century, soon after the French Revolution, auctions came to be held in taverns and coffeehouses to sell art. Such auctions were held daily, and catalogs were printed to announce available items. Such Auction catalogs are frequently printed and distributed before auctions of rare or collectible items. In some cases these catalogs were elaborate works of art themselves, containing considerable detail about the items being auctioned.
Sotheby's, now the world's second-largest auction house,[11] held its first auction in 1744. Christie's, now the world's largest auction house,[11] was established around 1766. Other early auction houses that are still in operation include Dorotheum (1707),Mallams (1788), Bonhams (1793), Phillips de Pury & Company (1796), Freeman's (1805) and Lyon & Turnbull (1826).[13]

During the American civil war goods seized by armies were sold at auction by the Colonel of the division. Thus, some of today's auctioneers in the U.S. carry the unofficial title of "colonel". [9]

The development of the internet, however, has led to a significant rise in the use of auctions as auctioneers can solicit bids via the internet from a wide range of buyers in a much wider range of commodities than was previously practical.[5]

In 2008, the National Auctioneers Association reported that the gross revenue of the auction industry for that year was approximately $268.4 billion, with the fastest growing sectors being agricultural, machinery, and equipment auctions and residential real estate auctions.

Types of auction

Primary types of auction

Multi-unit auctions sell more than one identical item at the same time, rather than having separate auctions for each. This type can be further classified as a uniform price auction or a discriminatory price auction.

Secondary types of auction

Time requirements

Each type of auction has its specific qualities such as pricing accuracy and time required for preparing and conducting the auction. The number of simultaneous bidders is of critical importance. Open bidding during an extended period of time with many bidders will result in a final bid that is very close to the true market value. Where there are few bidders and each bidder is allowed only one bid, time is saved, but the winning bid may not reflect the true market value with any degree of accuracy. Of special interest and importance during the actual auction is the time elapsed from the moment that the first bid is revealed to the moment that the final (winning) bid has become a binding agreement.

Auctions: characterization

Auctions can differ in the number of participants:

Prices are bid (or offered) by buyers and asked by sellers. Auctions may also differ by the procedure for bidding (or asking, as the case may be):

Auctions may differ as to the price at which the item is sold, whether the first (best) price, the second price, the first unique price or some other. Auctions may set a reservation price which is the least/maximum acceptable price for which a good may be sold/bought.

Without modification, auction generally refers to an open, demand auction, with or without a reservation price (or reserve), with the item sold to the highest bidder.

Common uses for auctions

Auctions are publicly and privately seen in several contexts and almost anything can be sold at auction. Some typical auction arenas include the following:

Although less publicly visible, the most economically important auctions are the commodities auctions in which the bidders are businesses even up to corporation level. Examples of this type of auction include:

Bidding strategy

Bid shading

Bid shading is placing a bid which is below the bidder's actual value for the item. Such a strategy risks losing the auction, but has the possibility of winning at a low price. Bid shading can also be a strategy to avoid the Winner's curse.

Chandelier or Rafter Bidding

A practice, especially by high-end art auctioneers, of raising false bids at crucial times in the bidding process in order to create the appearance of greater demand or to extend bidding momentum for a work on offer. To call out these nonexistent bids, auctioneers might fix their gaze at a point in the auction room that is difficult for the audience to pin down.

In the United Kingdom, this practice is legal on property auctions up to but not including the reserve price, and is also known as off-the-wall bidding.[44]

Collusion

Whenever bidders at an auction are aware of the identity of the other bidders there is a risk that they will form a "ring" and thus manipulate the auction result, a practice known as collusion. By agreeing to bid only against outsiders, never against members of the "ring", competition becomes weaker, which may dramatically affect the final price level. After the end of the official auction an unofficial auction will take place among the "ring" members. The difference in price between the two auctions will then be split among the members.

A ring can also be used to increase the price of an auction lot, in which the owner of the object being auctioned may increase competition by taking part in the bidding him or herself, but drop out of the bidding just before the final bid. In Britain and many other countries Rings and the bidding on one's own object are illegal. This form of a ring was used as a central plot device in an episode of the British television series Lovejoy (series 4, episode 3) in which the price of a watercolour by the (fictional) Jessie Webb is inflated in order that others by the same artist can be sold for more than their purchase price.

In an English auction a dummy bid is a bid made by a dummy bidder acting in collusion with the auctioneer or vendor, designed to deceive genuine bidders into paying more. In a First price auction a dummy bid is an unfavourable bid designed so as not to become the winning bid. (The bidder does not want to win this auction, but he or she wants to make sure to be invited to the next auction).

In Australia a dummy bid (shill, schill) is a criminal offence but a vendor bid or a co-owner bid below the reserve price is permitted, if clearly declared as such by the auctioneer. These are all official legal terms in Australia, but may have other meanings elsewhere. A co-owner is one of two or several owners (who disagree among themselves).

In Sweden and many other countries there are no legal restrictions, but it will severely hurt the reputation of an auction house that knowingly permits any other bids except genuine bids. If the reserve is not reached this should be clearly declared.

Suggested opening bid (SOB)

There will usually an estimate of what price the lot will fetch. In an ascending open auction it is considered important to get at least a 50-percent increase in the bids from start to finish. To accomplish this, the auctioneer must start the auction by announcing a suggested opening bid (SOB) that is low enough to be immediately accepted by one of the bidders. Once there is an opening bid, there will quickly be several other, higher bids submitted. Experienced auctioneers will often select an SOB that is about 45 percent of the (lowest) estimate. Thus there is a certain margin of safety to ensure that there will indeed be a lively auction with many bids submitted. Several observations indicate that the lower the SOB, the higher the final winning bid. This is due to the increase in the number of bidders attracted by the low SOB. When 50 bidders compete, the winning bid will be about twice as high as when only two bidders compete. Sometimes with an English auction there will be more than 50 bidders.

A chi-squared distribution shows many low bids but few high bids. Bids "show up together"; without several low bids there will not be any high bids.

Another approach to choosing an SOB: The auctioneer may achieve good success by asking the expected final sales price for the item, as this method suggests to the potential buyers the item's particular value. For instance, say an auctioneer is about to sell a $1,000 car at a sale. Instead of asking $100, hoping to entice wide interest (for who wouldn't want a $1,000 car for $100?), the auctioneer may suggest an opening bid of $1,000; although the first bidder may begin bidding at a mere $100, the final bid may more likely approach $1,000.

Auction terminology

JEL classification

The Journal of Economic Literature (JEL) classification code for auctions is D44.[45]

See also

Further reading

Notes

  1. ^ Sotheby's (2007-06-07) (PDF), Sotheby's Sets a New World Record for Sculpture at Auction, http://files.shareholder.com/downloads/BID/340155988x0x110223/36c23cb5-958d-4a86-b517-ea6f9d297127/110223.pdf, retrieved 2008-06-20 
  2. ^ New York Times (2008-01-10), "Artemis and Stag at Met Museum", The New York Times, http://www.nytimes.com/2008/01/10/arts/10arts-ARTEMISANDST_BRF.html, retrieved 2008-06-20 .
  3. ^ *Melikian, Souren (2005-07-26), Chinese Jar Sets Record for Asian Art, The New York Times, http://www.nytimes.com/2005/07/13/arts/13iht-web.melik.html, retrieved 2008-06-19 
  4. ^ a b c d e f Krishna, 2002: p2
  5. ^ a b "The Heyday of the Auction", The Economist 352 (8129): 67–68, 1999-07-24, ISSN 0013-0613 
  6. ^ a b c d Shubik, 2004: p214
  7. ^ Krishna, 2002: p1
  8. ^ a b c Shubik, 2004: p215
  9. ^ a b Doyle, Robert A.; Baska, Steve (November 2002), "History of Auctions: From ancient Rome to todays high-tech auctions", Auctioneer, archived from the original on May 17, 2008, http://web.archive.org/web/20080517071614/http://auctioneersfoundation.org/news_detail.php?id=5094, retrieved 2008-06-22 
  10. ^ Patten, R. W. (Summer, 1970), "Tatworth Candle Auction", Folklore (London, United Kingdom: Taylor & Francis, Ltd. on behalf of Folklore Enterprises, Ltd.) 81 (2): 132–135, ISSN 0015-587x, JSTOR 1258945 
  11. ^ a b c Varoli, John (2007-10-02), "Swedish Auction House to Sell 8 Million Euros of Russian Art", Bloomberg.com News (Moscow: Bloomberg Finance L.P.), http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=20601088&sid=aGlwT7.MHwzw&refer=muse, retrieved 2008-06-21 
  12. ^ About the company, Stockholm, Sweden: Stockholms Auktionsverk, archived from the original on May 22, 2008, http://web.archive.org/web/20080522014917/http://www.auktionsverket.se/historike.htm, retrieved 2008-06-21 
  13. ^ Stoica, Michael (August 2007), The Business of Art, http://www.washburn.edu/mabee/crc/courses/auctionhouses.html, retrieved 2008-06-21 
  14. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l m n McAfee, R. Preston; McMillan, John (1987), "Auctions and Bidding", Journal of Economic Literature (American Economic Association) 25 (2): 699–738, June 1987, JSTOR 2726107, http://vita.mcafee.cc/PDF/JEL.pdf, retrieved 2008-06-25 
  15. ^ eBay, Selling Multiple Items in a Listing (Dutch Auction), http://pages.ebay.com/help/sell/multiple.html, retrieved 2009-01-09 
  16. ^ Krishna, 2002: p13
  17. ^ a b Krishna, 2002: p9
  18. ^ Krishna, 2002: p3
  19. ^ Milgrom, 2004: p119
  20. ^ Nasri, Grace (2011-04-07). "The Seduction of the Penny Auction". Huffington Post. http://www.huffingtonpost.com/grace-nasri/the-seduction-of-the-penn_b_846221.html. Retrieved 2011-04-27. 
  21. ^ a b c d e f Gallien, Jérémie; Gupta, Shobhit (May 2007), "Temporary and Permanent Buyout Prices in Online Auctions", Management Science (INFORMS) 53 (5): 814–833, doi:10.1287/mnsc.1060.0650, ISSN 1526-5501, http://mansci.journal.informs.org/cgi/content/abstract/53/5/814 
  22. ^ a b Pekec, Aleksandar; Rothkopf, Michael H. (November 2003), "Combinatorial auction design.", Management Science (INFORMS) 49 (11): 1485–1503, doi:10.1287/mnsc.49.11.1485.20585, ISSN 1526-5501, http://mansci.journal.informs.org/cgi/content/abstract/53/5/814 
  23. ^ http://www.auctusdev.com/auctiontypes.html
  24. ^ [1]
  25. ^ a b c Fisher, Steven (2006), The Real Estate Investor's Handbook: The Complete Guide for the Individual Investor, Ocala, Florida: Atlantic Publishing Company, pp. 89–90, ISBN 091062769X 
  26. ^ a b c d Good, Steven L.; Lynn, Paul A. (January 2007), "The eBay Effect", Commercial Investment Real Estate (CCIM Institute), http://www.ciremagazine.com/article.php?article_id=1036, retrieved 2009-06-25 
  27. ^ Leichman, Laurence (1996), 90% off! real estate, Ocala, Florida: Leichman Assoc Pubns, pp. 78–79, ISBN 0963686771 
  28. ^ Schoenherr, Tobias; Mabert, Vincent A. (September–October 2007), "Online reverse auctions: Common myths versus evolving reality", Business Horizons (Kelley School of Business, Indiana University) 50 (5): 373–384, doi:10.1016/j.bushor.2007.03.003 
  29. ^ http://www.scribd.com/doc/39032383/Electronic-Reverse-Auction-and-the-Public-Sector-Factors-of-Success-Moshe-E-Shalev-Stee-Asbjorensen. Shalev Moshe and Asbjornsen Stee, "ELECTRONIC REVERSE AUCTIONS AND THE PUBLIC SECTOR – FACTORS OF SUCCESS", Journal of Public Procurement, 10(3) 428-452.
  30. ^ a b c d e Isaac, R. Mark; Schnier, Kurt (October 2005), "Silent auctions in the field and in the laboratory", Economic Inquiry (Oxford, United Kingdom: Western Economic Association International) 43 (4): 715–733, doi:10.1093/ei/cbi050, ISSN 0095-2583, http://ideas.repec.org/a/oup/ecinqu/v43y2005i4p715-733.html 
  31. ^ Milgrom, 2004: p268
  32. ^ Ab Hugh, Dafydd. A Balance of Power. Star Trek Press, 1995
  33. ^ a b Milgrom, 2004: p267
  34. ^ Milgrom, 2004: p267-268
  35. ^ Peter, Cramton (2006), "Simultaneous Ascending Auctions", in Cramton, Peter; Shoham, Yoav; Steinberg, Richard, Combinatorial Auctions, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, ISBN 978-0262033428 
  36. ^ http://www.ssc.wisc.edu/~dquint/econ805%202007/econ%20805%20lecture%2012.pdf
  37. ^ http://en.wikiversity.org/wiki/Economic_Classroom_Experiments/Private_Value_Auctions
  38. ^ Canadian Museum of Civilization and Canada Postal Museum - Auction of Fine Art and Stamps
  39. ^ The Land Newspaper, Prime sheep, Rural Press, 13 August 2009.
  40. ^ Combined factors hit wool auctions hard
  41. ^ William Inglis & Son Limited
  42. ^ d'Arcy, Susan (2010-01-24). "Bag a holiday bargain in an online auction". The Times (London). http://www.timesonline.co.uk/tol/travel/news/article6998942.ece. 
  43. ^ Pickles Auctions
  44. ^ http://ukauctions.org.uk/articles-videos/help-and-advice/what-is-bidding-off-the-wall/
  45. ^ Journal of Economic Literature Classification System, American Economic Association, http://aea-web.org/journal/jel_class_system.html, retrieved 2008-06-25  (D: Microeconomics, D4: Market Structure and Pricing, D44: Auctions)

References