William Phillips (economist)
From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
A.W. ("Bill") Phillips (1914 – March, 1975) was born Alban William Phillips in New Zealand. He became an influential economist, spending most of his academic career at the London School of Economics (LSE). He also had an interesting war record. His best-known contribution is the Phillips curve, which he first described in 1958. He also designed and built the MONIAC hydraulic economics computer in 1949.
Contents |
[edit] Early life
Born the son of a Albanian immigrants to New Zealand, Alban William Phillips first name honors that heritage. He left New Zealand before finishing school to work in Australia at a variety of jobs, including crocodile hunter and cinema manager. In 1937 Phillips headed to China, but had to escape to Russia when Japan invaded China. He traveled across Russia on the Trans-Siberian Railway and made his way to Britain in 1938, where he studied electrical engineering. At the outbreak of World War II, Phillips joined the Royal Air Force and was sent to Singapore. When Singapore fell, he escaped on the troopship Empire State, which came under attack before safely arriving in Java. When Java, too, was overrun Phillips was captured by the Japanese, and spent three and a half years interned in a prisoner of war camp in Indonesia. During this period he learned Chinese from other prisoners, repaired and miniaturised a secret radio, and fashioned a secret water boiler for tea which he hooked into the camp lighting system. In 1946 he was made a Member of the Order of the British Empire (MBE) for his war service. After the war he moved to London and began studying sociology at the London School of Economics, because of his fascination with prisoners of war's ability to organize themselves. But he became bored with sociology and interested in Keynesian theory, so he switched his course to economics and within nine years was a professor of economics.
[edit] Economics career
While Phillips was a student at the LSE he developed an analogue computer which used hydraulics to model the workings of the British economy. It was called the Monetary National Income Automatic Computer or MONIAC, which was probably a backronym reminiscent of the American ENIAC computer. The flow of water through its tanks and pipes accurately simulated the flow of money through the economy. The MONIAC Computer’s ability to model the subtle interaction of economic parameters, such as tax rates and investment rates made it a powerful tool for its time. Phillips first demonstrated MONIAC to a number of leading economists at the LSE in 1949. It was very well received and Phillips was soon offered a teaching position at the LSE. He advanced from assistant lecturer in 1951 to professor in 1958.
His work focused on British data, and observed that in years when the unemployment rate was high, wages tended to be stable, or possibly fall. Conversely, when unemployment was low, wages rose rapidly. This sort of pattern had been noticed earlier by Irving Fisher, but in 1958 Phillips published his own work on the relationship between inflation and unemployment, illustrated by the Phillips Curve. Soon after the publication of Phillips' paper the idea that there was a trade-off between a strong economy and low inflation caught the imagination of academic economists and policy-makers alike. Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow wrote an influential article describing the possibilities suggested by the Phillips curve in the context of the United States. What people think of as the Phillips curve has changed substantially over time, but remains an important feature of macroeconomic analysis of economic fluctuations. Had he lived longer, Phillips' contributions may have been worthy of a Nobel prize in economics.
Phillips made several other notable contributions to economics, particularly relating to stabilization policy. This approach to economics reflects his earlier training as an engineer, something that was evident in his construction of a physical model of an economy complete with pipes and water flowing around to represent the flow of transactions between different sectors.
He returned to Australia in 1967 for a position at York University which allowed him to devote half his time to Chinese studies. In 1969 the effects of his war deprivations and smoking caught up with him. He had a stroke and left Toronto, prompting an early retirement and return to Auckland, New Zealand, where he died in March, 1975.
[edit] References
- Mike Hally, Electronic Brains: Stories from the Dawn of the Computer Age, Joseph Henry Press, 2005, ISBN 0-309-09630-8
[edit] See also
[edit] External links
- "When Money Flowed Like Water" article from September 1995 Inc. magazine, accessed April 11, 2006
- Catalogue of the Phillips papers at the Archives Division of the London School of Economics.