Progressive tax

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Public finance
This article is part of the series:
Finance and Taxation
Taxation
Income tax  ·  Payroll tax
CGT ·  Stamp duty  ·  LVT
Sales tax  ·  VAT  ·  Flat tax
Tax, tariff and trade
Tax haven
Tax incidence
Tax rate  ·   Proportional tax
Progressive tax  ·   Regressive tax
Tax advantage

Economic policy
Monetary policy
Central bank  ·   Money supply
Gold standard
Fiscal policy
Spending  ·   Deficit  ·   Debt
Policy-mix
Trade policy
Tariff  ·   Trade agreement
Finance
Financial market
Financial market participants
Corporate  ·   Personal
Public  ·   Regulation
Banking
Fractional-reserve
Full-reserve  ·   Free banking
Islamic

 view  talk  edit  project

A progressive tax is a tax that imposes a greater percentual burden on the rich than on the poor. The opposite is a regressive tax.[1][2] which imposes a greater percentual burden on the poor than on the rich. Due to the very high level meaning of the term, there can be significant.

Progressive tax does not necessarily refer to something that grows as the numbers involved grow as is the case with progressive income tax. A hypothetical tax on luxury goods can have a flat rate (meaning that the tax is same for a necklace worth 10.000 as it is for a necklace worth 1.000.000) and the tax remains a progressive tax. Yet the most commonly referenced form of progressive taxation is the personal income tax, where people with more disposable income pay a higher percentage of that income in tax than do those with less income.

In between progressive and regressive taxation is a proportional taxation (flat tax is close to this), where the tax rate is fixed. The proportional taxes are only used for incomes, as taxes on consumption could only be made proportional if the buyer's income would be included in the taxes applied. Progressive taxes attempt to reduce the tax incidence of people with a lower ability-to-pay, as they shift the incidence disproportionately to those with a higher ability-to-pay.

The whole topic of progressive taxation can be split in to two distinct categories:

There are also some mixups with progressivism the ideology, under which high gas taxes might be called progressive (since they are pro-nature, which would be considered progressive). However, gas taxes are actually extremely regressive in developed countries. It is interesting to note that the development status of a country affects whether a given consumption tax is regressive or progressive: in a country where the majority of the population goes to work in a car (for example the USA) gas tax is regressive, whereas it would be progressive in a country where only the rich have cars.

Contents

[edit] History of intellectual debate about progressive taxation

The debate regarding progressive taxation has been somewhat confused as the consumption and income sides of the equation tend to be mixed especially in populist public discourse. As economists understand the combination:

Regressive Income Taxation Proportional Income Taxation Progressive Income Taxation
Regressive Consumption Taxation Extremely Regressive Regressive Unclear
Progressive Consumption Taxation Unclear Progressive Extremely Progressive

Considering there is no option that would be "proportional", the obvious choices come down to whether people would prefer progressive or regressive. There are few reasons except cronyism to actually favor regressive taxation, which has historically been the best way to create an uprising (in particular the extremely regressive food and alcohol taxes have caused numerous uprisings). This leaves most economists and political scientists supporting either the progressive or extremely progressive stances in the previous table. And indeed the idea of a progressive taxation has garnered support from economists and political scientists of many different ideologies - ranging from Adam Smith to Karl Marx, although there are differences of opinion about the optimal level of progressivity. Some economists[3] trace the origin of modern progressive taxation to Adam Smith, who wrote in The Wealth of Nations:

The necessaries of life occasion the great expense of the poor. They find it difficult to get food, and the greater part of their little revenue is spent in getting it. The luxuries and vanities of life occasion the principal expense of the rich, and a magnificent house embellishes and sets off to the best advantage all the other luxuries and vanities which they possess. A tax upon house-rents, therefore, would in general fall heaviest upon the rich; and in this sort of inequality there would not, perhaps, be anything very unreasonable. It is not very unreasonable that the rich should contribute to the public expense, not only in proportion to their revenue, but something more than in that proportion.[4]

In most western European countries and the United States, advocates of progressive taxation tend to be found among the majority of economists and social scientists who realize that completely proportional taxation is not even a possibility.[5][6][7] In the U.S., the vast majority of economists (81%) support progressive taxation.[5][6][7]


[edit] Progressive Income Taxation

The key concept of progressive income taxation is that income is considered in different steps, where income earned between certain points will be taxed at a certain rate. This is done to avoid creating incentive traps, where earning more might actually decrease your income (if income up to 10.000 is untaxed and after 10.001 you pay 10%, you will receive 9.000,9 if you make 10.001 and 10.000 if you make 10.000).

The size and severity of the different steps varies a great deal and the differences inside the term "progressive" can be enormous. In this sense it is not surprising that most economists support progressive taxation to some degree - the primary differences come when looking at the maximum income taxes that the highest earners might have to pay.

[edit] Reasons for implementation

  • As income levels rise, levels of consumption tend to fall. Thus it is often argued that economic demand can be stimulated by reducing the tax burden on lower incomes while raising the burden on higher incomes.
  • It is also argued that people with higher income tend to have a higher percentage of that in disposable income, and can thus afford a greater tax burden (this is the “vertical equity” argument). Some would claim that a person earning exactly enough money to pay for food and housing cannot afford to pay any taxes without it causing material damage, while someone earning twice as much can afford to pay up to half their income in taxes.
  • Some believe that the wealthy have a disproportionately greater interest in maintaining societal goods typically supported by taxation such as security of property rights, defense and infrastructure, as they have much more to lose if these fail than do the poor. Public investments in defense and foreign aid often support assets abroad whose expropriation is a far greater risk than is the risk involving domestic investments.
  • A progressive tax is an automatic stabilizer in the sense that if a person were to suffer a decrease in wages due to a recession then the money regained by being in a lower tax bracket lessens this blow.
  • It is inherent in tax policy that it implements economic and social policy. People who are concerned about a runaway, cancerous character in the global economy, greenhouse gases, etc., see benefits in progressive taxation, both in its braking effect on the economy and in helping shape economic activities towards necessities more effectively than purely monetary or fiscal policies.
  • As long as after-tax income is a strictly increasing function of gross income, there is a monetary incentive to increase compensation received. Indeed, for any particular income goal, the higher the tax rate, more compensation one must receive to reach that income goal. For this reason, progressive income tax may increase the incentive to produce among the largest producers (if higher production is truly associated with higher compensation).

[edit] Arguments against implementation

Arguments against progressive taxation tend to be found among libertarians and some conservatives. Among economists and social scientists, and to a lesser extent the general population, opponents of progressive taxation tend to be in the minority.[8][9][10]

  • Progressive taxes lower savings rates. High-earners have a lower average propensity to consume, so shifting the tax-burden away from them will increase the aggregate savings rate, which should increase steady state growth (if the savings rate is initially below the Golden Rule savings rate).
    • The classical argument against progressive taxation runs as follows:

      The diminishing returns argument applies to the fraction of income used for present consumption. As income rises, diminishing returns implies that a smaller and smaller fraction of income will be spent on consumption goods. The remaining income will (of necessity) be used to purchase capital goods. This acts as a form of positive feedback that in turn yields more income for capital spending. Meanwhile (and because) these capital goods induce a decline in the costs of production which has the effect of raising real wages generally and implicitly raising the general standard of living. The income paid back on the capital helps create the disincentive to consume that creates capital spending. Thus, those capitalists who effectively manage their property are rewarded and given control of more (newly created) property, of which they are increasingly less inclined to consume and increasingly more inclined to purchase capital goods and thus further elevate the general standard of living by driving down the costs of production. As they acquire more capital goods, eventually their ownership outstrips their ability to manage and oversee what they own; however, they only control as many capital goods as can be attributed to the income of their prior capital---which previously did not exist. Therefore, their ownership does not negatively contribute to the general standard-of-living relative to counterfactual state of them not purchasing those goods. It would thus be misleading to argue that redistributing their capital may yield further increases in the standard-of-living. Doing so may well cause that effect, but doing so neglects that it was the assumption that redistribution would not happen that induced the accumulation of capital. — Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk, Karl Marx and the Close of his System, 1896)

    • A belief that progressive taxation shifts the total economic production of society away from capital investments (tools, infrastructure, training, research) and toward present consumption goods. This could happen because high-income earners tend to pay for capital goods (through investment activities) and low-income earners tend to purchase consumables. Smithian and neo-classical growth theory says that spending more on consumption goods and less on capital goods will slow the rise of the standard of living, and possibly even reduce it since capital goods increase future production possibilities.
  • Brain drain and tax avoidance. High progressive taxes may encourage emigration because taxes are not internationally harmonized, so very high earners are sometimes able to relocate in order to pay less tax, or find tax havens for their income. Unlike the opposing income effect and substitution effect of leisure which may make tax progressivity neutral in terms of working hours, the emigration rate can only increase with the top rates of tax.[citation needed]
    • The differential in the higher rates of tax between the United States and Europe are cited as a factor in the "brain drain" of high-earners to America in the 1960s, and is considered an important influence on modern "economic migration."[citation needed]
  • Increase in tax loopholes such as income splitting techniques. This creates an incentive for business owners to split their business into smaller, less efficient ones for a lower tax bracket. It also encourages production from less efficient smaller businesses than larger ones.
  • The increasing energy expended on tax avoidances which occur with greater progressivity produces an increase in the work of accountants and lawyers. Because tax avoidance creates no net wealth this work is unproductive, and can make taxes on the rich less efficient than on the middle class, who have less motivation to exploit tax loopholes.[citation needed]
  • Progressive taxes are argued to create work disincentive. Consider again someone who makes twice the minimum required to live on, but pays all income above the minimum living threshold in taxes. Such a person had no monetary incentive at all to try to increase his or her income above the base level.[11]
  • Justice in representation. Economic equity is sometimes used to argue against progressive taxation, on the grounds of representation being out-of-proportion to taxation: While the top 5% in income in most countries pay over half the taxes[12] they only have 5% of the voting weight. This argument can be reversed into the plutocratic case that if tax is to be progressive it should be accompanied by greater say in elections for those who contribute most.
  • Policymakers are argued to be under a pressure from lower and middle income voters to limit higher incomes by the means of progressive taxation. A few economists argue against inequity aversion: "If policy makers' primary goal is … economic prosperity for all, they should avoid focusing on the politics of envy." (Gregory Mankiw)[13]
  • A study from the libertarian Institute for Policy Innovation, which aims to reduce government intervention in the economy, has concluded that progressive taxes fail to decrease real income inequality.[14]

[edit] Marginal and effective tax rates

The rate of tax can be expressed in two different ways, the marginal rate expressed as the rate on each additional piece of income (or last dollar spent) and the effective (average) rate expressed as the total tax paid divided by total income. In most progressive tax systems, both rates will rise as income rises, though there may be income ranges where the marginal rate will be constant. With a system of negative income tax, refundable tax credits, or income-tested welfare benefits, it is possible for marginal rates to fall as income rises: this can still be seen as progressive providing that the marginal rate is higher than the average rate at any particular level of income, since the average rate will rise as income rises; high marginal rates for those on low incomes can lead to a poverty trap within a progressive system, even if they face negative average rates.

[edit] Measuring Progressivity

The progressivity of a tax can be expressed by its Suits index or the Gini Coefficient.


[edit] Personal income tax brackets

[edit] United States

See also: Income tax in the United States and Taxation in the United States

The progressive aspects of the Federal income tax rates in the United States have varied widely since 1913. For example, in 1954 the Congress imposed a Federal income tax on individuals, with the tax imposed in layers of 24 income brackets at tax rates ranging from 20% to 91% (for a chart, see Internal Revenue Code of 1954). As of 2006, there are six "tax brackets" ranging from 10% to 35% used to calculate the percentage of taxable income (of individuals) that must be paid to the United States Treasury. If taxable income falls within a particular tax bracket, the individual pays the listed percentage of income on each dollar that falls within that monetary range. For example, a person who earned $10,000 in taxable income (income after adjustments, deductions, and exemptions) for 2006 would be liable for 10% of each dollar earned from the 1st dollar to the 7,550th dollar, and then for 15% of each dollar earned from the 7,551st dollar to the 10,000th dollar, for a total of $1,122.50. This ensures that every rise in a person's salary results in an increase of after-tax salary. The Treasury Department in 2006 reported, based on Internal Revenue Service (IRS) data, the share of all federal taxes paid by taxpayers of various income levels. The data shows the progressive structure of the U.S. federal tax system that reduces the tax incidence of people with smaller incomes, as they shift the incidence disproportionately to those with higher incomes - the top 0.1% of taxpayers by income pay 17.4% of all federal taxes (earning 9.1% of the income), the top 1% pay 36.9% (earning 19%), the top 5% pay 57.1% (earning 33.4%), and the bottom 50% pay 3.3% (earning 13.4%).[15]

However, if the federal taxation rate is compared with the wealth distribution rate, which was studied in A Rolling Tide: Changes in the Distribution of Wealth in the U.S. by Arthur Kennickell at Levy Economics Institute, the net wealth (not only income but also including real estate, cars, house, stocks, etc) distribution of the United States does almost coincide with the share of income tax - the top 1% pay 36.9% of federal tax (wealth 32.7%), the top 5% pay 57.1% (wealth 57.2%), top 10% pay 68% (wealth 69.8%), and the bottom 50% pay 3.3% (wealth 2.8%).[16] Other taxes in the United States with a less progressive structure or a regressive structure, and legal tax avoidance loopholes change the overall tax burden distribution. For example, the payroll tax system is regressive on income with no standard deduction or personal exemptions taxing only the first $97,500 for 2007 from gross wages, and none earned from capital investments or interest. The Center on Budget and Policy Priorities states that three-fourths of U.S. taxpayers pay more in payroll taxes than they do in income taxes.[17]

[edit] United Kingdom

For more details on this topic, see Taxation in the United Kingdom.

The United Kingdom has the following progressive income tax brackets (all values in Pound sterling): 20% from £2231 to £34,600 and 40% for £34,600 and above. These taxation rates are only applicable, of course, for taxable income. For those aged 18-65 and not in full time education, the income tax allowance (the amount of income against which no income tax will be levied) is £5225.

[edit] New Zealand

For more details on this topic, see Taxation in New Zealand.

New Zealand has the following progressive income tax brackets (all values in New Zealand dollars with earner levy included): 19.5% up to $38,000, 33% from $38,001 to $60,000, 39% above $60,001, and 49% when the employee does not complete a declaration form (IR330).[18] In New Zealand, the income is taxed by the amount that falls within each tax bracket. In other words, if a person earns $60,000, they will only pay 33% on the amount that falls between $38,001 and $60,000 rather than paying this on the full $60,000.

[edit] Australia

For more details on this topic, see Taxation in Australia.

Australia has the following progressive income tax brackets (all values are in Australian dollars): 0% up to $6000, 15% from $6001 to $25000, 30% from $25001 to $75000, 40% from $75001 to $150000, and 45% tax for any amount over $150000. These taxes are paid throughout Australia.

[edit] Inflation and tax brackets

Many tax laws are not accurately indexed to inflation. Either they ignore inflation completely, or they are indexed to the Consumer Price Index (CPI), which tends to understate real inflation.[19] In a progressive tax system, failure to index the brackets to inflation will eventually result in effective tax increases (if inflation is sustained), as inflation in wages will increase individual income and move individuals into higher tax brackets with higher percentage rate. One example is the United States Alternative Minimum Tax; since it is not indexed to inflation,[20][21] an increasing number of upper-middle-income taxpayers have been finding themselves subject to this tax.

[edit] See also

[edit] Notes

  1. ^ Webster (3): decreasing in rate as the base increases (a regressive tax)
  2. ^ American Heritage (3). Decreasing proportionately as the amount taxed increases: a regressive tax.
  3. ^ Stein, Herbert (1994, April 6). "Board of Contributors: Remembering Adam Smith." Wall Street Journal (Eastern Edition), p. PAGE A14. Retrieved January 8, 2008, from Wall Street Journal database. (Document ID: 28143064).
  4. ^ Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature And Causes of the Wealth of Nations (1776). Book Five: Of the Revenue of the Sovereign or Commonwealth. CHAPTER II: Of the Sources of the General or Public Revenue of the Society. ARTICLE I: Taxes upon the Rent of House.
  5. ^ a b Klein, D. B.; Stern, C. (2004-12-06). Economists' policy views and voting. Public Choice Journal. Retrieved on 2007-07-02.
  6. ^ a b Boxx, W. T. & Quinlivan, G. M. (1994). The Cultural Context of Economics and Politics. Lanham, MA: University Press of America.
  7. ^ a b Klein, G. P. (2006-11-15). Why Intellectuals Still Support Socialism. Ludwig Von Mises Institute. Retrieved on 2007-08-21.
  8. ^ Klein, D. B. & Stern, C. (6 December, 2004) Economists' policy views and voting. Public Choice Journal.. Retrieved on 2007-07-02.
  9. ^ Boxx, W. T. & Quinlivan, G. M. (1994). The Cultural Context of Economics and Politics. Lanham, MA: University Press of America.
  10. ^ Klein, G. P. (15 November, 2006). Why Intellectuals Still Support Socialism. Ludwig Von Mieses Institute. (Survey results were taken from a tetriary source in this case). Retrieved on 2007-08-21.
  11. ^ When the ‘optimal’ tax rates are derived in economic models it is almost always assumed that: (1) Increasing labour leads to increasing dis-utility, (2) the more ‘productive’ high-earners will make a choice between consumption and work that makes them at least as well off as lower-rate tax payers (a “self-selection constraint”). With these two assumptions, mathematical models maximizing various social ‘objectives’ can be designed but (excluding compulsion) all require some increase in consumption for higher-tax payers. For an example of this constraint in the most redistributive model (the Rawlsian model) see page 4 of: Optimal Income Taxation and the Ability Distribution: Implications for Migration Equilibria from Jonathan Hamilton and Pierre Pestieau (2002).
  12. ^ . Tax breakdown for the United States from the IRS which shows this pattern. The Economist magazine tends to rate the U.S. tax codes as being surprisingly progressive (below the levels of the super-rich) – perhaps because U.S. citizens rarely emigrate or move away from urban centres. However, in comparison to European social democratic countries, U.S. rates are certainly not unusually progressive, and many countries have any even greater proportional "disenfranchisement" of the rich.
  13. ^ Reply by Gregory Mankiw to the June 7, 2005 NYT editorial: “The Bush Economy”
  14. ^ http://www.ipi.org/ipi%5CIPIPublications.nsf/PublicationLookupFullTextPDF/7412EB9AFBB4D28786256B4D00738EBE/$File/PR162-Hartman-Redistribution.pdf?OpenElement
  15. ^ Incomes and Politics, Wall Street Journal, September 02, 2006
  16. ^ Kennickell, Arthur (2003-03). A Rolling Tide: Changes in the Distribution of Wealth in the U.S., 1989-2001. United States Federal Reserve. Retrieved on 2007-09-19.
  17. ^ Kamin, David; Shapiro, Isaac (2004-09-13). Studies Shed New Light on Effects of Administration's Tax Cuts. Center on Budget and Policy Priorities. Retrieved on 2006-07-23.
  18. ^ The actual tax rates on the NZ Inland Revenue site (with examples).
  19. ^ Waggoner, John. "If you think inflation is on the move, time to protect portfolio" (HTML), USA Today, 2004-11-26. Retrieved on 2008-02-03. 
  20. ^ TPC Tax Topics Archive: The Individual Alternative Minimum Tax (AMT): 11 Key Facts and Projections
  21. ^ Falling Into Alternative Minimum Trouble (washingtonpost.com)

[edit] External links

Wikiquote has a collection of quotations related to: