New Economic Mechanism

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

The New Economic Mechanism (NEM) was a major economic reform launched in the People's Republic of Hungary in 1968.

Contents

[edit] Reform

The period from 1956-1968 was one of reform in Eastern Europe. The beginning of these transformations was marked by the Hungarian Revolution of 1956 which resulted in János Kádár’s placement as the communist leader of the People's Republic of Hungary and the creation of the Hungarian Socialist Workers' Party (HSWP). For the first ten years of his rule, Kádár’s objective was to create a united Hungary, announcing in December 1961 “that those who are not against us are with us.” Having reached social peace, Kádár turned his attention to economic improvement.

On May 7, 1966, the Central Committee of the HSWP announced Kádár’s plans for the reform of the economy, known as the New Economic Mechanism(NEM).[1] The reform was the “most radical postwar change” of any Comecon country.[2] The plan, which became official January 1, 1968, was a major shift to decentralization in an attempt to overcome the inefficiencies of central planning. The NEM represented a move away from the Stalin economic system of compulsory plan indicators in favor of a policy that states profits as the enterprises main goal. The new economic policy was a “comprehensive reform of the economic system,” creating market relationships among firms, using prices as allocative functions and firms responding to prices to maximize profits, and using profits to budget new investments.[1]

[edit] Enterprises

The Central Committee’s document on May 7 details changes in the firm’s role under the new economic policy. The reform gave producers the freedom to decide what and how much they produce and offer for sale and to establish commercial or co-operative relationships. Buyers were also given the freedom to choose between domestic goods and imports. Additionally, firms were given greater autonomy in carrying out investments and hiring labor. As dictated by the Central Committee, success is to be measured by a firm’s profitability.[1] The decentralized structure of the New Economic Mechanism marked an improvement in the decision making process, allowing for basic decisions to be made at the local level without information having to be transmitted upward for a more centralized decision.[2] The Hungarian government made 50.5%(enterprises 49.5%) of the investment decisions for the 68 billion Forint invested in 1968, while in 1974 enterprises accounted for 53.1% of the decisions for the 128 billion Forint invested.[3]


[edit] Prices

The New Economic Mechanism also aimed to create a more active role for prices.[4] A system of free prices reflecting market conditions was implemented. The government wanted flexibility, but also to combat inflation. To do so, they introduced a new practice of price controls declaring an item’s price as fixed, limited or free.

Fixed prices were classified as material and basic intermediate goods. The price was fixed because of the good’s impact on the economy and the overall need to ensure stability. The price was determined by ministries.

Limited prices referred to particular products or products in some product group for which there were no substitutes, such as bread. It was applied on the average price over a period or a window within which prices are free to fluctuate.

Free prices were assigned to goods that have small parts of individual expenditures or were regarded as luxuries.[4]

The price reform allowed for prices to better reflect the cost of production, valuation by the market and to correspond more closely to “some measure of socially necessary inputs,”[4] helping reach market equilibrium.


[edit] Foreign Trade

The goal of the New Economic Mechanism was in improving Hungary’s economy to make Hungary a serious contributor to the international economy. In 1966 the Soviet Union accounted for 32% of Hungary’s exports and 29% of its imports. Of Hungary’s exports to Western Developed Countries, 42.7% was Food and Live Animals, 43.5% Manufactured Goods. Meanwhile trade with Socialist Countries consisted largely of Manufactured Goods(81.3%). Alternatively, Hungary’s imports from the West were primarily Manufactured Goods(70.6% of Western imports).[1] Because of the pre-existing quota system which placed an emphasis on quantity, not quality, Hungarian goods were inferior and did not meet Western technological standards.

Decentralization provided enterprises with the opportunity to better align with the world market by giving them more freedom in deciding which products and technologies to invest in and manufacture. Additionally, firms were paid for exports in the equivalent Hungarian currency of the foreign currency they earned as the government aimed to concern enterprises with foreign markets and improving the quality of goods produced.[2] The new plan established direct connections between the foreign and domestic markets on the basis of an appropriate exchange rate.[2] The primary concern of the New Economic Mechanism was in improving foreign trade and establishing a relationship between success in exportation and a firm’s profitability.[1]


  1. ^ a b c d e Balassa, Bela. “The Economic Reform in Hungary.” Economica, New Series, Vol. 37, No. 145. (Feb., 1970), pp 1-22.
  2. ^ a b c d Granick, David. “The Hungarian Economic Reform.” World Politics, Vol. 25, No. 3. (Apr., 1973), pp. 414-429.
  3. ^ Das Gupta, K.K.. “The Nature of Post-Reform Economic Management in Eastern Europe: The Hungarian Case.” Social Scientist, Vol. 9, No. 1. (Aug., 1980), pp. 3-17.
  4. ^ a b c Hare, P.G. “Industrial Prices in Hungary Part I: The New Economic Mechanism.” Soviet Studies, Vol. 28, No. 2. (Apr., 1976), pp. 189-206.