History of the English fiscal system

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

The history of the English fiscal system affords the best known example of continuous financial development in terms of both institutions and methods. Although some periods of great upheaval occurred from the time of the Norman Conquest to the beginning of the 20th century, the line of connection is almost entirely unbroken. Perhaps the most revolutionary changes occurred in the 17th century as a result of the Civil War and, later, the Glorious Revolution of 1688; though even then there was no real breach of continuity.

The primitive financial institutions of early England centred round the king's household. In other words, the royal preceded the national economy in importance. Revenue dues collected by the king's agents, rents, or rather returns of produce from land, and special levies for emergencies formed the main elements of the royal income which gradually acquired greater regularity and consistency. There is, however, little or no evidence of what modern governments recognise as financial organization until the 11th century. The influence exercised from Normandy, which so powerfully affected the English rulers at this time, tended towards the creation of records of revenue claims as well as a central treasury.

Contents

[edit] Systematizing finance

With the union of England and Normandy under the same head, the idea of settled administrative methods became fixed and of special importance in the financial sphere. The systematizing spirit, so characteristic of both the Norman and Angevin kings, produced the great institution of the exchequer with its judicial and administrative sections and its elaborate forms of account and control. Even before this organization was developed, the Domesday Book, now recognized as having a purely fiscal object (in Maitland's words a tax book, a geld book), shows the movement towards careful observation of all sources of revenue. It is clear that William I of England. initiated a policy which was followed by his successors despite the serious difficulties during the anarchy that subsisted in Stephen's nominal reign. The obscure question as to the real origin of the special contrivances employed by the exchequer is, strictly speaking, irrelevant to the financial inquirer, who may be content to hold that, granting the existence of some Old English analogies, the system, as it appears in the 12th century, was a product peculiar to the conceptions of fiscal organization formed by Norman subtlety. Indeed, its importance lies in the manner in which the institution held together, focussing as it does on the revenues and expenditure of the kingdom. The picture presented by the Dialogue of the Exchequer (c. 1176) is that of a comprehensive system which secured the receipt of the royal income and providing a thorough audit of accounts by employing processes adapted to the circumstances of the time. It is, in fact, through the description of financial institutions that it is possible to ascertain the forms of revenue held by the crown. Thus, the ingenuity expended on the exchequer's administrative machinery had as its aim the increase of the king's resources, a subject in which all politically involved churchmen and lawyers were deeply involved.

[edit] Royal and feudal prerogative

In order to understand the character of English finance in the Middle Ages, it is essential constantly to bear in mind the identification of the king with the state. Although feudalism was, in one of its aspects, a powerful instrument for the division of political authority, the particular form in which the Conqueror introduced it to England nevertheless enabled the fiscal rights of the crown to be established more strictly than was possible under previous conditions. First, the actual property of the crown was better administered as each royal manor became subject to the new system of accounting. Again, the king's various claims or dues took on a more decidedly feudal character, thus receiving stricter legal definition. Further, the higher judicial organizations assisted the expansion of court fees while, above all, the increased authority of the state made the casual receipts (for such they were) from trade more profitable.

[edit] Sources of revenue

Broadly, the sources of revenue fall under the following heads:

  1. The royal estates, which were distributed throughout England, derived in part from the possessions of the old English kings. These were increased by the confiscations following the events of the Conqueror's reign plus the doctrine which stated that unowned land belonged to the king (terra regis). Over fourteen hundred manors appear as royal property in Domesday. The forests, placed under special laws, yielded little revenue except in the form of offender penalties. Rural tenants at first paid rent in produce but this was gradually substited by money. As the royal demesne was favorable to the growth of towns, the rents derived from urban tenants became a valuable part of the demesne's yield. This later took the form of town payments as units (the firma burgi), a method which secured to the burghers freedom from sheriffs' exactions, which were purchased by special payments.
  2. The feudal rights, which included the claim to military service, the three regular aids and payments of relief on succession to a fief, as well as the profits on wardships and marriages with escheats and forfeitures completing the list. The yields from these sources varied with the power of the king and were kept within bounds by the resistance of tenants as shown in the provisions of Magna Carta.
  3. The administration of justice was a lucrative prerogative of the crown. Suitors had to pay not only for the hearing of their cases but also fees for writs. Additionally, both amercements and compositions increased receipts from this source.
  4. Two special classes contributed to the exchequer. First, as much of the country's wealth was in the hands of the church, the opportunity afforded by keeping sees, abbacies and priories vacant enabled the king advantageously to redirect their revenues to himself. Secondly, until their expulsion, the Jews were an even more profitable source of revenue. Being under the absolute control of the crown, they could be taxed at will either by taking percentages of their property (e.g. in one instance, one-fourth), or by levies for alleged offences. In fact, the existence of a separate exchequer for the Jews is an indication of their fiscal value.
  5. Direct taxation formed an extraordinary or occasional head of revenue. The Danegeld was succeeded by the carucage, and the commutation of military service introduced the scutage. However, these forms were of little immediate importance albeit becoming very significant for the future course of development.
  6. Lastly came the dues claimed at the ports which were trivial in amount but which nevertheless contained the germ the customs system of later years, even though they now resemble the harbour charges of modern ports.

The history of the English financial system consists mainly of the different fortunes of the above exchequer receipts. For example, a sheriff was bound to account for all local contributions before onward transmission to the king for the service of the state. During the century and a half that lay between the Conquest and the granting of the Great Charter, this held good. Nevertheless, the character of the ruler affected the vigour of both fiscal and general, administration. For instance, Henry I and Henry II of England secured far better results than either Stephen or John, even though the collection of rent and profit from the royal manors together with feudal and other dues continued as the mainstay of the revenue. However, indications of change are to be found, and the substitution of the carucage or plough tax for the Danegeld marks an advance towards direct taxation of land through its produce. Moreover, the introduction of scutage is not only further evidence of the same tendency, but also a step toward the development of a money-based economy to replace the earlier system of payments in kind. The special levies or tallage imposed on towns in the kings demesne at times of need appear to have been a doubtful exercise of the royal prerogative, albeit belonging scientifically to the same class as the Danegeld and scutage. But perhaps the most important advance made in this period was the beginning of taxation on movables, first applied in the Saladin tithe of 1189 later expanding into a general system.

In the reign of John of England (1199-1216), the loss of Normandy and concession to the barons' demands set out in the Magna Carta rendered financial readjustment inevitable. During the long reign of Henry III of England, the struggle to maintain the privileges granted by the Charter acted on the fiscal system by checking the arbitrary use of tallages and, as a consequence, encouraged the regular assessment of a tax on movables, which became more prevalent over time. The fruitful idea that it was necessary to obtain the consent of tax payers before its imposition operated powerfully in favour of the establishment of bodies representing the various social classes. Indeed, the reaction of constitutional on fiscal development led to the transition from feudal to parliamentary taxation in its earliest forms.

[edit] Direct taxation

Almost at the beginning of the age of parliamentary taxation, one of the older sources of revenue ceased. The pressure of popular opinion forced Edward I to expel the Jews (1290) despite his desire to retain such profitable subjects. Indeed, it is probable that, owing to the exactions practised on them, Jewish usurers had become less useful to the exchequer. Certainly, the kingdom's general resources had so increased that their contribution became less important.

The first effects of parliamentary influence on the fiscal domain were the abandonment of tallages on towns and the decline of scutage. Taxes on movables were framed more systematically so that, instead of distinct charges on different classes or variations in the proportions of levy, e.g. from one-fourth to one-fortieth, tax was imposed at the levels of one-tenth on towns and one-fifteenth on counties. Commissioners supplied with special instructions as to taxible and exempt goods were appointed for each county to ensure stricter assessment. This tax remained in force from 1290-1334, albeit that sometimes the proportions imposed varied (e.g. an eighth and a fifth granted in 1297, and a tenth and a sixth in 1322).

A more general influence was the growing national economy which led to greater activity on the part of the king as administrator which, in turn, increased the state's need for revenue. Although constitutionally the king was expected to live off his revenues, the force of events made this increasingly impracticable. Therefore, from being uncertain and indirect, taxation, especially that on movables, became certain and direct, absorbing older forms over time. Under medieval conditions, the collection of a general property tax presented serious difficulties in that, unsurprisingly, each local and borough authority tried to keep assessments as low as possible.

England in the 14th century was not ripe for a system that was found hard to make effective even in more advanced societies. Hence, from 1334 onward, the following method of apportionment was employed, i.e. a tenth and fifteenth was taken as affording a definite sum measured by the yield on the ancient valuation. As this gave between 38,000 and 39,000 in the aggregate, the tenth and fifteenth became for the future practically a fiscal expression for a sum of about 39,000, the total to be divided or apportioned between the several counties, cities and boroughs according to their former payments. This settlement, which remained in force for centuries and affected all later direct taxes, had the great advantages of certainty and adaptability. The inhabitants of any particular town knew their total liability and could distribute it amongst themselves in the manner most convenient to themselves. From the royal standpoint, the arrangement was also satisfactory, for the tenth and fifteenth could be multiplied (e.g. in 1352 three tenths and fifteenths were voted for three years), and supplied a stable revenue for the service of the kingdom. Moreover, the power of regulating the policy of the crown by the bestowal or refusal of grants was naturally agreeable to parliament. Thus, all sections of the nation united in support of the system established in 1334, just before the opening of the Hundred Years' War, in connection with which it was particularly serviceable.

[edit] Poll tax

Akin to the above - at any rate in its nature as a direct impost - was the poll or capitation tax. Financial pressure at the close of Edward IIIs reign (1377) led to the adoption of a tax of fourpence per head on all persons in the kingdom (mendicants and persons under fourteen years being excepted). This tallage of groats, which seems to be derived by analogy from the hearth money for Peter's pence, was followed by the graduated poll taxes of 1379 and 1380, the former rangeing in scale from ten marks imposed on royal dukes and viscounts, to six marks on earls, bishops and abbots down to three on barons and to the groat or fourpence on all other persons over sixteen years of age.

As Adam Smith saw it, this accorded to a form of income tax. In the event, it proved to be unproductive, only half the estimated yield of £50,000 being obtained. Indeed, the tax of 1380 varied within narrower limits - from twenty shillings to fourpence (or sixty groats to three), with the proviso that the strong should aid the weak. However, this particular tax is chiefly memorable as the occasion that may have been the real causes of the great Peasants Revolt of 1381.

This unlucky association sealed the fate of the poll tax as a fiscal expedient. It was abandoned, with one exception, for nearly three hundred years, its occasional employment in the 17th century not resulting in its permanent revival. Apart from special circumstances, it is plain that the tenth and fifteenth was better suited than the poll tax for the purpose of English finance.

The machinery for collection was ready for the former, while special agents had to gather the latter, even from the poorest classes. In fact, the episode of the poll taxes may be regarded as a fortunately uncessful attempt to relieve the propertied classes at the expense of the peasants and poorer burghers. Failure in this respect helped in the maintenance of the settlement of direct taxation devised in 1334.

[edit] Indirect taxation

Parallel with the evolution of direct taxation, but decidedly lagging behind, is the progress of indirect taxation. As already mentioned, the right of levying dues on goods entering or leaving English ports belonged from very early times to the king. Whether this power was, in its origin, due to the protection afforded to traders and thus a kind of insurance, or the result of the royal prerogative of pre-emption is immaterial for finance. What is established is that the prisage of wine or levy of one cask in ten, and the taking of one-tenth or one-fifteenth of other commodities was in force. Attempts to impose additional dues were forbidden by the important article (41) of the Great Charter which recognized the ancient and just customs.

One of the earliest effects of parliamentary influence is manifested in the establishment of duties on wool, woolfells and leather by the first parliament of Edward I. After efforts by the king to gather increased duties, the Confirmation of the Charter (1297) forbade any increases on the amounts fixed in 1275, which were henceforth known as the ancient customs.

Another attempt was made to obtain a higher scale of duties by arrangement with merchants. Foreign traders consented to the royal proposals, which comprised duties on wine, wool, hides and wax, plus a general tax of 13/4% on all imports and exports. Thus, in addition to the old custom of half a mark (6s. 8d.) per sack of wool and each three hundred woolfells, as well as one mark (13s. 4d.) per last or load of leather, foreign merchants paid an extra duty (or surtax) of 50% and also 2s. per tun of wine, the so-called butlerage.

The privileges laid down in the Carta Mercatoria (1303) were probably granted conditionally on the acceptance of these enhanced dues. English merchants, however, successfully resisted them so that the old prisage of wine remained unchanged, at least for them. Despite parliamentary opposition on the ground that they amounted to an infringement of the Great Charter, the new customs remained in force. After being suspended in 1311, they were revived in 1322, confirmed by royal authority in 1328, and finally sanctioned by parliament in the Statute of the Staple (1353). They therefore formed part of the permanent crown revenues from the ports and, together with other, older, customs, became the basis for further development.

Just as the old direct taxes were supplemented by, and then absorbed into, the general taxation on movables, so customs, in the strict sense, were followed by subsidies or parliamentary grants. One great source of English wealth in the 14th century was the export of a peculiarly fine wool. Thus, the political circumstances of Edward III's time suggested its manipulation for purposes of both policy and revenue. Sometimes in order to influence the towns of Flanders, the export of wool was absolutely prohibited; at others, varying export duties were imposed not only on wool, but also skins and leather. In the reign's early years, these were settled in agreement with merchant classes.

These subsidies were first imposed in 1340, being henceforward granted despite frequent complaints. Thus, in 1348, parliament objected to an export duty of 2% per sack on wool on the ground that it was in fact a tax on landowners who, as a consequence, received lower prices for their wool. Bargains between the king and merchants were forbidden and were therefore brought under parliamentary control by statutes passed in 1362 and 1371. In 1347, besides special duties on wool, imposts on wine and general goods were increased by agreement at a charge of 25% per tun on the former and 2 3/4% on the latter. Indeed, between 1371 and 1376, these were established as grants under the names Tunnage and Poundage, older dues being left intact.

[edit] The clergy

The clergy occupied a peculiar position in that it still claimed the privilege of self-taxation so that convocation rather than parliament voted the tenths imposed on its property. In some instances, far heavier charges (e.g. one third in 1296) were decreed by the king, despite which such taxation became less productive during the 14th century. However, by the close of the reign of Richard II, the results of the transition from feudalism to a parliamentary constitution were almost complete. As regards finance, the most important of these were:

  1. The disappearance or reduction of unimportant feudal dues. The fact that this change occurred at a relatively early date is of special significance for English development.
  2. The royal demesne, though it had not yet suffered the losses that later grants were to inflict, had also lost some of its value.
  3. In compensation, direct taxation on property became a ready means of supplying the growing requirements of the administration, the mode of levy being reduced to a well-recognized form, unsatisfactory experiments such as the poll tax having been withdrawn.
  4. The growth of import and export duties through the old and new customs plus subsidies furnished a large part of the requisite funds. In fact, in a little over three hundred years and without violence, the constituent parts of public income had been completely altered in relative value and organization.

The Lancastrian era, extending over two thirds of the 15th century (1399-1471), is noticeable for introducing new forms of direct taxation. The standard tax, the tenth and fifteenth, was failing to meet changing conditions in that, as towns decayed, further allowances had to be given amounting to over 15% (~6000), which, with other deductions, lowered the yield from tenths and fifteenths to 31,000. To supplement this, a 5% land tax affecting only large land owners was introduced in 1404, a lower rate of 13/4% being applied to the less wealthy in 1411. A house tax made its appearance in 1428 while taxes on knights' fees and other freeholds were also tried. In 455 and 450, a graduated income tax was employed. The minimum rate, 23/4%, applied to incomes under 100 (or under 20 in the tax of 1450) rising to 10% on higher incomes, thus evidencing the need for greater revenue. Interestingly at this time, such methods showed a disposition to adopt foreign models, particularly those of France and Italy.

As to indirect taxation, receipts at first seemed to decline so that subsidies were granted for specified fixed terms, albeit that the victory of Agincourt gained a life grant for Henry V. After the enthronement of Edward IV, however, the tenth was literally taken up and voted (1472) by Parliament as a special military provision only. However, it failed to raise the necessary revenue, thus forcing the king to fall back on older forms of grant.

Extra taxes on aliens were levied under both Lancastrian and Yorkist rulers but with little profit. The most original contribution of Edward IV's reign to fiscal policy was that of benevolences or payments by wealthy subjects of sums requested by the king. Voluntary in form, these were, in fact, compulsory, and later became one of the great grievances against which parliament had to struggle.

Broader financial issues marked the Tudor period as the era of national monarchies arrived, necessitating the maintenance of greater military and naval forces, as well as more costly machineries of administration. Both external and fiscal policy were affected by the set of ideas that developed into mercantilism while finance reflected the actions of a monarch's personal rule, particularly in the 16th century, so that decided contrasts could be found. For example, prudence, carried to the point of parsimony by Henry VII, was followed by the lavish prodigality of Henry VIII while Elizabeth's financial policy was very different from those of either. In addition, the desire for a vigorous foreign policy, the hope of encouraging native industry and the sentiment of retaliation against other countries' trade regulations interfered with the strict aim of earlier times - the obtaining of the largest possible yields.

The whole public economy was regarded as existing only for the furtherance of national power. It is this more complex policy together with new influences such as the discovery of America, the Renaissance and the Reformation that gives special interest to the financial problems of the sixteenth century.

The first head of public income at the disposal of the sovereign was that of the crown lands. Although these were diminished over time by grants to the king's relatives and favorites, they were simultaneously built up via resumptions and forfeitures. On the whole, though, losses and gains were thought to be in balance by the close of the 14th century. Crown lands were, however, an inelastic form of revenue, and their great impoverishment - begun in the 15th century by the Lancastrian kings, (in particular, Henry VI) - was caused through expenditure pressures, profligacy and wholesale plunder by officials.

Though the civil wars of the 15th century brought in many forfeited estates the grants of Edward IV kept down the increase; but the chief opportunity for aggrandizement was afforded by the dissolution of the monasteries and gilds under Henry VIII. The great mass of property that passed into the royal possession in this way was in part assigned to nobles and officials, while most of the remainder was distributed in the reigns of his children. The dwindling importance of the public revenue from land and rent charges is as noticeable under the Tudors as in earlier times. In like manner the feudal dues had fallen into a very subordinate place notwithstanding the attempts made on particular occasions to enforce them with greater rigour. The force of personal monarchy exercised by the Tudors, depending as it did on popular support, tended to encourage the collection of dues which had a legal ground in preference to taxation of the community. Of similar character was the employment of the old right of purveyance (qv.), in restraint of which a series of statutes had been passed.

Whatever possibilities of obtaining some additional revenue from the crown lands or prerogative rights may have existed in the 16th century, and these were slight, all the political and social conditions tended more and more to make the need of taxation as the principal financial resource imperative. Amongst the cases of increased calls for funds to maintain the machinery of state, the rise of prices, due to increased supplies of the precious metals, must be included as one of the chief, and its effect extends into the 17th century. It was under this influence that the old forms of revenue became less profitable and that fresh developments were necessitated.

Direct taxation still retained in one of its branches the pattern set in the reign of Edward III. Tenths and fifteenths continued to be voted, and for some time all attempts to introduce new methods failed. In 1488 a military grant framed on the model of the abortive tax of 1472 yielded only a little over one third of the estimate (~27,000 out of 75,000), and the unsatisfactory result prevented further experiments on the part of Henry VII. The foreign policy of Henry VIII, particularly his French expedition with its attendant outlay, accounts for the graduated capitation tax of 1513, which was even less in accordance with anticipation than the tax of 1488 (it yielded only ?S0,000? instead of 160,000). But these failures cleared the way for a more effective form of direct impost, which appeared in the subsidy or general tax on land and goods. The first case of this tax (1514) was a modest one 21/2%; it, however, soon took on a typical form, so that the subsidy came to mean a charge of 4S. in the pound on land and 2s. 8d. in the pound on goods, a scale evidently devised with reference to the older tenth and fifteenth, which was henceforth put in a subordinate position.

The subsidy became the established mode of grant under both Tudors and Stuarts, though by degrees it underwent a change similar to that experienced by its predecessor. The taxing statutes made elaborate provisions for the assessment and collection of the tax in order to secure a full return. Old habits proved too strong and the subsidy slipped into the same kind of groove as that of the fifteenth and tenth, and became, in practice, a grant of a sum of money of about the same amount as the yield of the last preceding subsidy (Dowell).

The consequence was that each subsidy came, in the middle of the 16th century, to be a sum of ?f00,000, and at its close only 80,000. The parallel vote of the clergy in convocation (which after 1533 had to be confirmed in parliament) amounted to 20,000. The usual parliamentary proceeding was to vote so many tenths and fifteenths and so many subsidies, e.g. Elizabeths first parliament voted her two fifteenths and tenths and a subsidy, or, taking the usual values, 160,000. At times of crisis such as the arrival of the Armada the votes were enlarged by granting more tenths and fifteenths and subsidies. The history of the subsidy is instructive as to the tendencies of direct taxation. in all countries. The assessment becomes inelastic and approximates to a fixed sum. As the subsidy follows the course of the later medieval taxation, so it is the undesigned model of the later land and property tax.

In the history of the port duties under the Tudors the first point for notice is the life grant to each of the sovereigns of the subsidies on wool, hides and leather, together with tunnage at 3S. and poundage at 5%; thus, with the hereditary customs, supplying a considerable revenue for the crowns use. No better indication of the increased power and popularity of the monarchy could be found. The contrast with the suspicious and grudging attitude of the Plantagenet and Lancastrian parliaments is significant of the change in national sentiment. A duty on maimsey (1490) had a retaliatory rather than a fiscal aim, being directed against the Venetians who had imposed restrictions on English trade. In several later cases wine became liable to extra duties, chiefly applied to French trade in further pursuance of the policy of retaliation.

Restrictions on import and export as well as the hostile measures against foreign merchants were matters of economic policy rather than finance, but they had the indirect effect of increasing the control exercised at the ports. The loss of Calais (1558) dislocated the system of the staple and cut off one centre of customs revenue; and it was also probably the cause of an important change in the mode of valuing goods for duty. For the declaration on oath of the merchant a fixed valuation was substituted and set forth in a book of rates, the first of its class (1558). Following this reform came more stringent regulations against smuggling and fraud on the part of officials. All through the Tudor period the cost of collection was unduly high. For the first six years of Elizabeth it has been estimated at one-sixth of the gross receipts.

Just as in the 14th century, the subsidy had followed the old and new customs, so in the 6th, the impositions levied by royal prerogative formed a supplement to the parliamentary subsidy, but the principal employment of this expedient occurs in the next century. Another significant indication of the future course of indirect taxation was furnished by the grants of monopolies to inventors, producers and traders. These privileges, when they affected important commodities, operated in the same way as taxes farmed out to collectors, and, though the profit to the crown was small, they enhanced prices and excited discontent. The wisdom of Elizabeth (or her ministers) was shown in the promise of redress after the hostile debate of 1601.

From one point of view it may fairly be said that the great struggle of the Stuart kings with the parliament centred round financial issues. It is, at all events, beyond dispute that questions of taxation were the chosen ground of conflict. Taking the period from the accession of James I to the opening of the Civil War (1642), it appears that the legal basis of indirect taxation was tested for the port duties in the Great Case of Impositions (known as the John Bates case), while that of direct taxation was considered in the even more famous Ship Money case (forever associated with the name of Hampden). In parliament the debates deal with impositions, monopolies, the grounds for voting subsidies, and the proper application of the funds granted in fact, with nearly all the financial questions of the time. Notwithstanding these difficulties and disputes the financial system shows evident signs of expansion and adaptation to the needs of the state.

The direct grants of the parliaments of James I. far exceeded those of earlier periods (in 1606 fifteenths and tenths, three lay and four clerical subsidies), but the efforts to extend the other sources of revenue by the exercise of the prerogative naturally reacted on this spirit of liberality. The last fifteenth and tenth was voted in 1624, from which date this old-established form disappears, and the subsidy alone is used. In spite of Charles Is high-handed policy, five subsidies were voted after the Petition of Right had been accepted, and even the Long Parliament made similar grants. Almost at the outbreak of the Civil War it also gave the king a graduated capitation tax.

Other modes of direct taxation were used without parliamentary sanction. The collection of the antiquated feudal dues was enforced through the special courts (particularly the Star Chamber) with a rigour long unknown; James had tried the French device of a tariff of honors. Both kings employed the benevolence until the Petition of Right made such a levy illegal. But by far the most serious innovation was the collection of the ship money, a course forced on Charles by his determination not to meet the representatives of the nation. The writs embodied the ultimate expression of the ingenuity of the kings advisers in the invention of means to enable him to rule without a parliament. The first writs secured over 100,000, and were followed by five further issues (1634-1639) bringing in an average return of 200,000 or about three lay subsidies. Like the benevolence, the ship money was declared to be illegal (1641).

The contest respecting monopolies, settled by Elizabeths withdrawal, was revived under James I, and had to be finally closed by the Statute of Monopolies (1624), declaring such grants to be utterly void. Certain exceptions (as in the case of the soapboilers) permitted the raising of revenue by what is in fact a rudimentary excise, and plans for a general excise were discussed, especially as a substitute for the feudal dues, though they were not reduced to practice. In the earlier 17th century the customs show a steady increase. From 127,000 in 1604 they rose to nearly 500,000 in 1641. This fourfold increase was due in part to the growth of English trade, but it was also influenced by the adoption of new books of rates in 1608 and 1635, fixing higher valuations, and by the inclusion of new commodities with definite duties. Wine, currants (the subject of controversy in Bates case) and tobacco are particularly noticeable. Sugar also appears as a contributory.

An interesting development was the adoption on a larger scale of the farming system, an evident imitation from France. A distinction was made between the great, the petty and the sugar farms, and opportunities for gain were afforded to the officials. On the constitutional side the life grant of subsidies, made in accordance with Tudor usage to James, was temporarily withheld from Charles, a restriction which his own overbearing policy led the parliament to maintain. Practically, the whole customs revenue between 1628 and 1640 was raised by the use of the prerogative without any parliamentary sanction. The Tunnage and Poundage Act of 1641 pronounced definitely against the legality of any extra parliamentary customs and thus closed another of the constitutional problems of finance.

In the progress from the Conquest to the crisis of the Great Rebellion there is noticeable a practically complete shifting of the classes of revenue. The king had ceased to live of his own; the royal demesne and the prerogative rights included in feudalism had become very subordinate. The direct taxation of property and income, and the indirect taxation on imported or exported commodities became the principal forms of receipt.

[edit] Civil war and commonwealth

In the long course of English financial history the nearest approach to the new departure and an abandonment of old devices is found at the time of the Civil War and Commonwealth. The actual outlines of the now existing system made their appearances, while the older portions of the revenue, particularly the survivals of feudalism are eliminated. Thus the Civil War and the Interregnum ?(164260)? may be regarded as marking a watershed in the financial history of the country. At the beginning of the struggle both sides had to rely on voluntary contributions. Plate and ornaments were melted down and useful commodities were furnished by the adherents of the king and by those of the parliament.

As holding possession of London and the central organization the parliament voted subsidies and a poll tax. Such imports could hardly be levied with success and new forms became necessary. The direct taxation took the shape of a monthly assessment which was fixed from time to time, and which was collected under strict regulations, in marked contrast to the lax management of the former subsidies. As the amount for each district was fixed, the systematic collection secured the more equitable adjustment of the burden of the tax as regards the various taxpayers without hardship to the community.

In spite of its origin, the assessment was the model for later taxation of property. The yield of this tax exceeding for the whole period 32,000,000 is a proof of its importance. Minor contrivances, e.g. the weekly meal tax, indicate the financial difficulties of the parliament, but are otherwise unimportant. Owing to its control of the sea and the principal ports the parliament was able to command the customs revenue; and in this case also it remodelled the duties, abolishing the wool subsidy and readjusting the general customs by a new book of rates. A more extensive tariff was adopted in 1656, and various restrictions in harmony with the mercantilist ideas of the time were enforced. Thus French wines, silk and wool were excluded from 1649 to 1656.

Far more revolutionary in its effects was the introduction of the excise or inland duties on goods, a step which Elizabeth, James I. and Charles I. had hesitated to take. Beginning (1643) with duties on ale, beer and spirits, it was soon extended to meat, salt and various textiles. Meat and domestic salt were relieved in 1647, and the taxation became definitely established under the administration of commissioners appointed for the purpose. Powers to let out the collection to farmers were granted, and a bid for both excise and customs amounted in 1657 to 1,100,000. Confiscations of church lands and those belonging to royalists, feudal charges and special collections helped to make up the total of 83,000,000 raised during the nineteen years of this revolutionary period.

Another mark of change was the removal of the exchequer to Oxford, leaving, however, the real fiscal machinery at the disposal of the committees that directed the affairs of the parliament. Under Cromwell the exchequer was re-established (1654) in a form suited for the changes in the finances, the office of treasurer being placed in the hands of commissioners.

[edit] The Restoration

A complete reconstruction of the revenue system became necessary at the Restoration. The feudal tenures and dues, with the prerogative rights of purveyance and pre-emption, which had been abolished by order of the parliament, could not be restored. Their removal was confirmed, and the new revenues that had been developed were resorted to as a substitute. Careful inquiry showed that just before the Civil War the kings annual revenue had reached nearly 900,000. The needs of the restored monarchy were estimated at 1,200,000 per annum, and the loyal spirit of the commons provided sources of revenue deemed sufficient for this amount. An hereditary excise on beer and ale was voted as a compensation for the loss of the feudal dues, and temporary excises on spirits, vinegar, coffee, chocolate and tea were added.

All differences of old and new customs and subsidies had disappeared under the Commonwealth. The general or great statute (1660) provided a scale of duties 5% on imports and exports, with special duties on wines and woollen cloths accompanied by a new book of rates. A house tax, levied after the French pattern, on each hearth, was introduced in 1662 and became established. Poll taxes were used as an extraordinary resource, as were the last subsidies, voted in 1663, and then forever abandoned. Licences on retailers and fees on law proceedings were further aids to the revenue, which, in the later years of Charles II, and in the short reign of his successor, was with difficulty kept up to the level of the increasing expenditure.

The Commonwealth assessments were revived on several occasions, and indirect taxation was made more rigorous by the imposition of extra duties on brandy, tobacco and sugar, as also on French linens and silks. A very important development was the placing of the customs (1670) and the excise (1683) in the hands of special commissioners, instead of the system of farming them out to private collectors. The approach to modern conditions is further evidenced by the greater care in the administration. Amongst expert officials Dudley North (qv.), as commissioner of customs, was the most distinguished. In this period, too, the beginning of the public debt as in the appropriation of the bankers deposits may be found.

The Revolution of 1688 may be regarded both on its constitutional and financial sides as the completion of the work of the Long Parliament. In the latter respect its chief effects were:

  1. The transfer of the administration of the finances from the king's nominees to officials under parliamentary control
  2. The consequent application of the revenue to the purposes designated by parliamentary appropriation
  3. The rapid expansion of the various kinds of revenue, particularly the indirect taxes
  4. The rise and growth of the national debt, combined with the creation of an effective banking system. (The greater part of the 18th century was occupied with the working out of these results.)

The government of William III had to face the expenses of a great war and to allay discontent at home. As a preliminary step to the necessary settlement of the revenue a return was prepared, showing the tax receipts at over 1,800,000 and the peace expenditure at about 1,100,000. Parliament accepted the view that 1,200,000 per annum would suffice for the ordinary requirements of the kingdom. It, further, introduced the system of the Civil List and assigned ?00,00? for the fixed payments placed under that head, leaving the remainder to be appropriated for the other needs of the state. As the hearth money had proved to be a very unpopular charge, it was, in spite of its yield ?(~x70,000)?, given up. The temporary excise duties were voted for their majesties lives and the customs for a limited term. These branches of revenue were altogether insufficient to meet the pressure of the war outlay, and in consequence new heads of taxation or old ones revived came into use.

A series of poll and capitation taxes were imposed between 1689 and 1698, but were after that date abandoned for the same reason as that for the repeal of the hearth money. The monthly assessment was tried in 1688; then came an income tax followed by twelve months assessments in 1690 and 1691. The way was thus prepared for the property tax of 1692, imposing a rate of ?45? in the pound on real estate, offices and personal property. The old difficulties of securing returns made the tax chiefly one on land. It was under the name of the land tax that it was generally known. The 45. rate brought in 1,922,712, a return which declined in the following years. To meet this a fixed quota of nearly half a million ?(a Is. rate)? was adopted in 1697, the amount to be apportioned in specified sums to the several counties and towns. The framework of the tax remained without substantial change till 1798, the time of Pitts redemption scheme. In 1696 houses were taxed 2S. each, with higher rates for extra windows. The beginning of the window tax, licences on pedlars, and a temporary tax on the stocks of companies complete the imposts of this kind.

Stamp duties imitated from Holland were adopted in 1694 and extended in 1698; they mark the beginnings of the modern duties on transactions and the death duties. Large additions were made to the excise. Breweries and distilleries were placed under charge, and such important commodities as salt, coal, malt, leather and glass were included in the list of taxable articles, but the two last mentioned were soon relieved for the time. The customs rates were also increased. In 1698 the general 5% duty was raised by the new subsidy to 10%. French goods became liable to surtaxes, first of 25%, afterwards of 50%; those of other countries had to pay similar charges of smaller amount. Spirits, wines, tea and coffee were taxed at special rates.

How great was the expansion of the fiscal system may be best realized from the fact that during the comparatively short reign of William III (1689-1702) the land tax produced 19,20o,000, the customs 13,296,000, and the excise 13,650,000, or altogether 46,000,000. In the last year of the reign, the opening one of the 18th century, the returns from these taxes respectively were: land tax (at 2s.), 990,000, customs 1,540,000, excise 986,000, or a total exceeding three and a half million. The removal of the regular export duties in respect of domestic woollen manufactures, and corn, was the only alleviation of taxation, and in both cases it was due to special reasons of policy.

Quite as remarkable as the growth of revenue is the sudden appearance of the use of public loans. In earlier periods a ruler had accumulated treasure (Henry VII. left 1,800,000) or had pledged his jewels or the customs or occasionally the persons of his friends for the payment of his borrowings. Edward III.s dealings with the Florentine bankers are well known but it was only after the Revolution that the two conditions essential for a permanent public debt were realized:

  1. The responsibility of the government to the people
  2. An effective market for floating capital.

At the close of the war in 1697 a debt of 21,500,000 had been incurred, over 16,000,000 of which remained due at William III.s death. Connected with the public debt is the foundation of the Bank of England, which more and more became the agent for dealing with the state revenue and expenditure; though the exchequer continued to exist until 1834 as a real, even if antiquated institution.

Thus it is clear that by the end of the 17th century the new influences which date from the Civil War had brought into being all the elements of the modern financial system. Expenditure, revenue, borrowing to meet deficiencies are all, in a sense, developed into their present-day form. Increase in amount and some refinements in procedure, combined with improved views of public policy, are the only changes that occur later on.

Regarded broadly, the 18th and 19th centuries exhibit several distinct periods with definite financial aspects. In the ninety years from the death of William III. (1702) to the outbreak of the Revolutionary War with France (1793) there are four serious wars, covering nearly thirty-five years. There is the long peace administration of Walpole, and there are the shorter intervals of rest following each of the contests. From the beginning of the war with the French Republic to the year of Waterloo there is a nearly unbroken war time of over twenty years. The forty years peace is closed by the Crimean War (1854-56), and another forty years of peace ends with the South African War (1899-1902). During this time the older mercantilism passes into protectionism and this, again, gives way before the gradual adoption of the free trade policy. At each time of war, taxation (particularly in the indirect form) and debt increase. Financial reform is connected with the maintenance of peace. Among the great financial ministers Walpole, the younger Pitt, Peel and Gladstone are conspicuous; while Huskissons services in the kindred field of economic policy deserve special notice in their financial bearing.

By taking the several great heads of revenue in order it is comparatively easy to understand the nature of the progress made in subsequent years.

  1. The land tax, established on a definite basis in 1692, was the great 18th century form of direct taxation. Varying in rate from 1s. (as in 1731) to 4S. (as in most war years), it was converted by Pitt in 1798 into a redeemable charge on the lands of each parish, and by this process has sunk from the amount of 1,911,000 in 1798 to 730,000 in 1907-1908. The great increase in other heads had impaired the value of the land tax as a fiscal support.
  2. Parallel with the movement of the land tax but showing much more rapid growth was the excise of the 18th century. Most of the articles of common consumption were permanently taxed. Soap, salt, candles and leather are described by Adam Smith as taxed, and that taxation is unreservedly condemned by him. In 1739 the excise duties brought in 3,000,000. By 1792 they had risen to 10,000,000. Their continued expansion was due both to the wider area covered and to the increased consuming power of the country.
  3. The customs were equally serviceable, and in their case the increased duties were even more considerable. The general 10% of 1698 became 15% in 1704, a fourth 5% was imposed in 1748, and in 1759 the general duties were raised to 25%. Coincidentally with this general extension of the customs duties special articles such as tea were subjected to increased duties. The American War of Independence brought about a further general increase of 10%, together with special extra duties on tobacco and sugar. In 1784 the customs revenue came to over 3,000,000.

Two circumstances account for this slower growth.

  1. The extreme rigour of the duties and prohibitions, aimed chiefly against French trade; and
  2. The absence of care in estimating the point of maximum productiveness for each duty.

Swifts famous saying that in the arithmetic of the customs two and two sometimes, made only one is well exemplified in England at this time. The smuggler did a great deal of the foreign trade of the country. Efforts at reform were not, however, altogether wanting. Walpole succeeded in carrying several useful adjustments. He abolished the general duties on exports and also several of those on imported raw materials such as silk, beaver, indigo and colonial timber. His most ambitious scheme that for the warehousing of wine and tobacco in order to relieve exporters failed, in consequence of the popular belief that it was the forerunner of a general excise. Walpole's treatment of the land tax, which he kept down to the lowest figure (1s.), and his earlier funding plan deserve notice. His determination to preserve peace assisted his fiscal reforms. Pitts administration from 1783 to 1792 marks another great period of improvement. The consolidation of the customs laws (1787), the reduction of the tea duty to nearly one-tenth of its former amount, the conclusion of a liberal commercial treaty with France, and the attempted trade arrangement with Ireland, tend to show that Pitt would have anticipated many of the free trade measures of later years if it had been his lot to enjoy ten more years of peaceful administration.

One of the financial problems which excited the interest and even the alarm of the students of public affairs was the rapid increase of the public debt. Each war caused a great addition to the burden; the intervals of peace showed very little diminution in it. From sixteen millions in 1702, the debt rose to 53,000,000 at the treaty of ?IJtrecht? (1713). In 1748 it reached 78,000,000, at the close of the Seven Years' War it was 137,000,000, and when the American colonies had established their independence it exceeded 238,000,000. Apprehensions of national bankruptcy led to the adoption of the device of a sinking fund, and in this case Pitts usual sagacity seems to have failed him. The influence of R. Prices theory induced the policy of assigning special sums for debt reduction, without regard to the fundamental condition of maintaining a real surplus.

[edit] Income tax

The revolutionary and Napoleonic wars mark an important stage in English finance. The national resources were strained to the utmost, and the whip and spur of taxation was used on all classes of the community. In the earlier years of the struggle the expedient of borrowing enabled the government to avoid the more oppressive forms of charge, but as time went on every possible expedient was brought into play. One class of taxes had been organized during peace, the assessed taxes on houses, carriages, servants, horses, plate,? &c.? These duties were raised by several steps of 10% each until, in 1798, their total charge was increased threefold (for richer persons four or fivefold) under the plan of a triple assessment.

The comparative failure of this scheme (which did not bring in the estimated yield of 4,500,000) prepared the way for the most important development of the tax system, the introduction of the income tax in 1798. Though a development of the triple assessment, the income-tax was also connected with the permanent settlement of the land tax as a redeemable charge. It is possible to trace the progress of direct taxation from the scutage of Norman days through the tenth and fifteenth, the Tudor subsidies, the Commonwealth monthly assessments, and the 18th century land tax, to the income-tax as applied by Pitt, and, after an interval of disuse, revived by Peel (1842). The immediate yield of the income-tax was rather less than was expected (~6,000,000 out of 7,500,000), but by alteration of the mode of assessment from that of a general declaration to returns under the several schedules, the tax became, first at ?~%, afterwards at ?to%?, the most valuable part of the revenue. In 1815 it contributed 22% of the total receipts (ie. 14,600,000 out of 67,000,000). If employed at the beginning of the war, it would probably have obviated most of the financial difficulties of the government.

The window tax, which continued all through the 18th century, had been supplemented in the American War by a tax on inhabited houses (one of Adam Smiths many suggestions), a group to which the assessment taxes were naturally joined. During the 18th century the probate duty had been gradually raised, and in 1780 the legacy duty was introduced but these charges were moderate in character and did not affect land. Though the direct and quasi-direct taxes had been so largely increased, their growth was eclipsed by that of the excise and customs. With each succeeding year of war new articles for duties were detected and the rates of old taxes raised.

The maxim, said to have guided the financiers of another country wherever you see an object, tax it, would fairly express the guiding policy of the English system of the early 19th century. Eatables, liquors, the materials of industry, manufactures, and the transactions of commerce had in nearly all their forms to pay toll. To take examples: salt paid ?Iss.? per bushel; sugar 30s. per cwt.; beer ?ios.? per barrel (with 4S. 5d. per bushel on malt and a duty on hops); tea 96% ad valorem. Timber, cotton, raw silk, hemp and bar iron were taxed, so were leather, soap, glass, candles, paper and starch.

In spite of the need of revenue, many of the customs duties were framed on the protective system and thereby gave little returns; e.g. the import duty on salt in ?I8I~? produced 547, as against 1,616,124 from excise; pill-boxes brought in ?i8s.? ?jod.?, saltpetre 2d., with ?id.? for the war duties. The course of the war taxation was marked by varied experiments. Duties were raised, lowered, raised again, or given some new form in the effort to find additional revenue. Some duties, e.g. that on gloves, were abandoned as unproductive; but the conclusion is irresistible that the financial system suffered from over-complication and absence of principle. In the period of his peace administration Pitt was prepared to follow the teaching of The Wealth of Nations. The strain of a gigantic war forced him and his successors to employ whatever heads of taxation were likely to bring in funds without violating popular prejudices. Along with taxation, debt increased. For the first ten years the addition to it averaged ?27,000,ooc? per annum, bringing the total to over ?soo,00o,000.?

By the close of the war period in 1815 the total reached over 875,000,000, or a somewhat smaller annual increase a result due to the adoption of more effective tax forms, and particularly the income tax. The progress of English trade was another contributing agency towards securing higher revenue. The import of articles such as tea advanced with the growing population; so that the tea duty of 96% yielded in 1815 no less than 3,591,000. It is, however, true that by the year just mentioned the tax system had reached its limit. Further extension (except by direct confiscation of property) was hardly possible. The war closed victoriously at the moment when its prolongation seemed unendurable.

A particular aspect of the English financial system is its relation to the organization of the finance of territories connected with the English crown. The exchequer may be plausibly held to have been derived from Normandy, and wherever territory came under English rule the methods familiar at home seem to have been adopted. With the loss of the French possessions the older cases of the kind disappeared. Ireland, however, had its own exchequer, and Scotland remained a distinct kingdom. The 18th century introduced a remarkable change. One of the aims of the union with Scotland was to secure freedom of commerce throughout Great Britain, and the two revenue systems were amalgamated. Scotland was assigned a very moderate share of the land tax (under one-fortieth), and was exempted from certain stamp duties. The attempt to apply selected forms of taxation custom duties (1764), stamp duties (1765), and finally the effort to collect the tea duty (1773) to the American colonies are indications of a movement towards what would now be called imperialist finance.

The complete plan of federation for the British empire, outlined by Adam Smith, is avowedly actuated by financial considerations. Notwithstanding the failure of this movement in the case of the colonies, the close of the century saw it successful in respect to Ireland, though separate financial departments were retained till after the close of the Napoleonic War and some fiscal differences still remain. By the consolidation of the English and Irish exchequers and the passage from war to peace, the years between ?181S? and 1820 may be said to mark a distinct step in the financial development of the country. The connected change in the Bank of England by the resumption of special payments supports this view. Moreover, the political conditions in their influence on finance were undergoing a revolution. The landed interest, though powerful at the moment, had henceforth to face the rivalry of the wealthy manufacturing communities of the north of England, and it may be added that the influence of theoretic discussion was likely to be felt in the treatment of the financial policy of the nation. Canons as to the proper system of administration, taxation and borrowing come to be noticed by statesmen and officials.

These influences may be followed out in their working by observing the chief lines of adjustment and modification that followed the conclusion of peace. Relieved from the extraordinary outlay of the preceding years, the government felt bound to propose reductions. With commendable prudence it was resolved to retain the income-tax at 5% (one-half of the former rate), and to join with this reduction the removal of some war duties on malt and spirits. Popular feeling against direct taxation was so strong that the income-tax had to be surrendered in toto, a course which seriously embarrassed the finances of the following years. For over twenty five years the income-tax remained in abeyance, to the great detriment of the revenue system. Its revival by Peel (1842), intended as a temporary expedient, proved its services as a permanent tax; it has continued and expanded considerably since. Both the excise and customs at the close of the war were marked by some of the worst defects of a vicious kind of taxation. The former had the evil effect of restricting the progress of industry and hampering invention.

The raw materials and the auxiliary substances of industry were in many cases raised in price. The duties on salt and glass specially illustrated the bad results of the excise. New processes were hindered and routine made compulsory. The customs duties were still more restrictive of trade; as they practically excluded foreign manufactures, and were both costly and in many instances unproductive of revenue. As G. R. Porter has shown, the really profitable customs taxes were few in number. Less than a score of articles contributed more than nineteen-twentieths of the revenue from import duties. The duties on transactions, levied chiefly by stamps, were ill-graded and lacking in comprehensiveness.

From the standpoint of equity the ground for criticism was equally plain. The great weight of taxation fell on the poorer classes. The owners of land escaped giving any return for the property that they held under the state, and other persons were not taxed in proportion to their abilities, which had been long recognized as the proper criterion.

The grievance as to distribution has been modified, if not removed, by the great development of:

  1. The income-tax
  2. The death or inheritance duties.

Beginning at the rate of 7d. per pound (1842-1854), the income-tax was raised to ?IS. 4d.? for the Crimean War, and then continued at varying rates reduced to 2d. in 1874, it rose to 5d., then in 1894 to 8d., and by 1909 appeared to be fixed as a minimum at Is., or 5% on income from property. The yield per penny on the has risen almost uninterruptedly. From 710,000 in 1842, it now exceeds f 2,800,000, though the exemptions and abatements are much more extensive. In fact, all incomes of 3 per week are absolutely free (~160 per annum is the precise exemption limit), and an income of 400 derived from personal exertion pays less than ??51/2d.?? per pound, or ??2~ %.?? The great productiveness of the tax is equally remarkable. From 5,600,000 in 1843 (with a rate of 7d.) the return rose to f32,380,000 in 1907-1908, having been at the maximum of 38,800,000 in 1902-1903, with a tax rate of 63/4%. The income-tax thus supplies about one-fifth of the total revenue, or one-fourth of that obtained by taxation.

Several fundamental questions of finance are connected with the taxation of income and have been dealt with by English practice. Small incomes claim lenient treatment; and, as mentioned above, this leniency means in England complete freedom. Again, earned incomes appear to represent lower ability to pay than unearned ones. Long refused on practical grounds (as by Gladstone and Lowe), the concession of an abatement of 25% on earned incomes of 2000 and under was granted in 1907. The question whether savings should be exempt from taxation as income has (with the exception of life insurance premiums) been decided in the negative. Allowances for depreciation and cost of repairs are partially recognized.

Far more important than these special problems is the general one of increased tax rates on large incomes. Up to 1908-1909 the tax above the abatement limit of 700 remained strictly proportional but opinion showed a decided tendency in favor of extra rates or a super tax on incomes above an assigned amount (e.g. 5000), and this was included in the budget of 1909-1910.

[edit] Estate duty

In close relation with the income-tax is the estate duty, with its adjuncts of Legacy and Succession Duties. After Pitts failure to carry the succession duty in 1796, no change was made till Gladstones introduction in 1853 of a duty on land and settled property parallel to the legacy duty on free personality. Apart from certain minor alterations, the really vital change was the extension in 1894 of the old Probate Duty into a comprehensive impost (entitled the Estate Duty) applicable to all the possessions of a deceased person. This Inheritance Tax to give it its scientific title operates as a complementary property tax, and is thus an addition to the contribution from incomes derived from large properties.

By graduation the charges on large estates in 1908-1909 (before the proposal for further increase in 1909-1910) came to 10% on 1,000,000, and reached the maximum of 15% at 3,500,000. From the several forms of the Inheritance Taxes the national revenue gained 14,500,000, with 41/2 millions as a supplementary yield for local finance.

The immense expansion of direct taxation is evident on comparing 1840 with 1908. In the former year the Probate and legacy duties brought in about one million; the other direct taxes; even including the House duty, did not raise the total to 3,000,000. In 1908 the direct taxation of property and income supplied 51,500,000, or one-third of the total receipts as against less than one-twentieth in 1840.

But though this wider employment of direct taxation a characteristic of European finance generally reduced the relative position of the taxation of commodities, there was a growth in the absolute amount obtained from this category of duties. There were also considerable alterations, the result of changes in the views respecting fiscal policy. At the close of the Great War the excise duties were at first retained, and even in some cases increased. After some years, reforms began. The following articles amongst others were freed from charge: salt (1825); leather and candles (1830); glass (1845); soap (1853); and paper (1860). The guiding principles were:

  1. The removal of raw materials from the list of goods liable to excise
  2. The limitation of the excise to a small number of productive articles
  3. The placing of the greater part (practically nearly the whole) of this form of taxation on alcoholic drinks

Apart from breweries and distilleries, the excise had little field for its work. The large revenue of 35,700,000 lfl 1907-1908 was derived one-half from spirits (17,700,000), over one-third from beer, while most Of the remainder was obtained from business taxation in the form of licences, the raising of which was one of the features of the budget in 1909. As a feeder of the revenue the excise might be regarded as, equal to the income-tax, but less to be relied on in times of depression.

Valuable as were the reforms of the excise after 1820, they were insignificant as compared with the changes in the customs. The particular circumstances of English political life have led to perhaps undue emphasis being placed on this particular branch of financial development. Between 1820 and 1860 the customs system was transformed from a highly complicated arrangement of duties, pressing with severity on nearly all foreign imports, into a simple and easily understood set of charges on certain specially selected commodities. All favors or preferences to home or colonial producers disappeared.

Expressed in financial terms, all duties were imposed for revenue only, and estimated in reference to their productiveness. An assimilation between the excise and customs rates necessarily followed. The stages of the development under the guidance of Huskisson, Peel, and Gladstone are commonly regarded as part of the movement for Free Trade but the financial working of the alteration is understood only by remembering that the duties removed by tens or by hundreds were quite trivial in yield, and did not involve any serious loss to the revenue.

Perhaps the most remarkable feature of the English customs of the 19th century was the steadiness of the receipts. In spite of trade depressions, discussion was likely to be felt in the treatment of the financial policy of the nation. Canons as to the proper system of administration, taxation and borrowing come to be noticed by statesmen and officials.

The exemption of raw materials and food; the absence of duties on imported, as on home manufactures; the selection of a small number of articles for duty; the rather rigorous treatment of spirits and tobacco, were the salient marks of the English fiscal system which grew up in the 19th century. The part of the system most criticised was the very narrow list of dutiable articles. Why, it was asked, should a choice be made of certain objects for the purpose of imposing heavy taxation on them?

The answer has been that they were taken as typical of consumption in general and were easily supervised for taxation. Moreover, the sumptuary element is introduced by the policy of putting exceptionally heavy duties on spirits and tobacco, with lighter charges on the less expensive wines and beers.

Facility of collection and distribution of taxation over a larger class appear to be the grounds for the inclusion of the tea and coffee duties, which are further supported by the need for obtaining a contribution of, roughly speaking, over half the tax revenue by duties on commodities. The last consideration led, at the beginning of the 20th century, to the sugar tax and the temporary duties on imported corn and exported coal.

As a support to the great divisions of income-tax, Death Duties, Excise and Customs, the stamps, fees and miscellaneous taxes are of decided service. A return of 9,000,000 was secured by stamp duties.

In recent years the so-called non-tax revenue largely increased, owing to the extension of the postal and telegraphic services. The real gain is not so great, as out of gross receipts of 22,000,000 over 17,500,000 is absorbed in expenses, while the carriage of ordinary letters seems to be the only profitable part of these services. Crown lands and rights (such as vintage charges) are of even less financial value.

One cardinal principle of the greatest English finance ministers has been the avoidance of deficits or undue surpluses. Gladstones inheritance of doctrine from Peel was to estimate expenditure liberally, to estimate revenue carefully, to make each year pay its own expenses, and to take care that your charge is not greater than your income. This method of treatment requires that taxation shall be productive in yield, and that it shall be so elastic as to admit of expansion, a function specially assigned to the income-tax. It may also be said to involve due care in the treatment of the national resources. The reaction of ill-chosen taxes on industry is a hindrance to their productiveness and their growth.

[edit] See also

[edit] References

This article incorporates text from the Encyclopædia Britannica Eleventh Edition, a publication now in the public domain.