Cobweb model
From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
The cobweb model or cobweb theory is an economic model that explains why prices might be subject to periodic fluctuations in certain types of markets. It describes cyclical supply and demand in a market where the amount produced must be chosen before prices are observed. Producers' expectations about prices are assumed to be based on observations of previous prices. The cobweb model was developed by the Hungarian economist Nicholas Kaldor.
Contents |
[edit] The model
The cobweb model is based on a time lag between supply and demand decisions. Agricultural markets are thought to be a situation where the cobweb model might apply, since there is a lag between planting and harvesting. Suppose for example that as a result of unexpectedly bad weather, farmers go to market with an unusually small crop of strawberries. This shortage, equivalent to a leftward shift in the market's supply curve, results in high prices. If farmers expect these high price conditions to continue, then in the following year, they will raise their production of strawberries relative to other crops. Therefore when they go to market the supply will be high, resulting in low prices. If they then expect low prices to continue, they will decrease their production of strawberries for the next year, resulting in high prices again.
This process is illustrated by the diagram on the right. The equilibrium price is at the intersection of the supply and demand curves. A poor harvest in period 1 means supply falls to Q1, so that prices rise to P1. If producers plan their period 2 production under the expectation that this high price will continue, then the period 2 supply will be high, at Q2. Prices therefore fall to P2 when they try to sell all their output. Notice that as this process repeats itself, oscillating between periods of low supply with high prices and then high supply with low prices, the price and quantity spiral inwards and the economy converges to the equilibrium price where supply and demand cross.
Simplifying, the cobweb model can have two main types of outcomes:
- If the slope of the supply curve is greater than the slope of the demand curve (in absolute value), then the fluctuations decrease in magnitude with each cycle, so a plot of the prices and quantities over time would look like an inward spiral, as shown in the diagram. This is called the stable or convergent case.
- If the slope of the supply curve is less than the slope of the demand curve (in absolute value), then the fluctuations increase in magnitude with each cycle, so that prices and quantities spiral outwards. This is called the unstable or divergent case.
Two other possibilities are:
- Fluctuations may also remain of constant magnitude, so a plot of the equilibria would produce a simple rectangle, if the supply and demand curves have exactly the same slope.
- If the supply curve is less steep than the demand curve near the point where the two curves cross, but more steep when we move sufficiently far away, then prices and quantities will spiral away from the equilibrium price but will not diverge indefinitely; instead, they may converge to a limit cycle.
In either of the first two scenarios, the combination of the spiral and the supply and demand curves often looks like a cobweb, hence the name of the theory.
[edit] Role of expectations
One reason to be skeptical about this model's predictions is that it assumes producers are extremely shortsighted. While assuming that farmers look back at the most recent prices in order to forecast future prices might seem very reasonable, this backward-looking forecasting (which is called adaptive expectations) turns out to be crucial for the model's fluctuations. When farmers expect high prices to continue, they produce too much and therefore end up with low prices, and vice versa.
In the stable case, this may not be an unbelievable outcome, since the farmers' prediction errors (the difference between the price they expect and the price that actually occurs) become smaller every period. In this case, after several periods prices and quantities will come close to the point where supply and demand cross, and predicted prices will be very close to actual prices. But in the unstable case, the farmers' errors get larger every period. This seems to indicate that adaptive expectations is a misleading assumption: how could farmers fail to notice that last period's price is not a good predictor of this period's price?
The fact that agents with adaptive expectations may make ever-increasing errors over time has led many economists to conclude that it is better to assume rational expectations, that is, expectations consistent with the actual structure of the economy. However, the rational expectations assumption is controversial since it may exaggerate agents' understanding of the economy. The cobweb model serves as one of the best illustrations of why understanding expectation formation is so important for understanding economic dynamics, and also why expectations are so controversial in recent economic theory.
[edit] Evidence
[edit] Livestock herds
The cobweb model has been interpreted as an explanation of fluctuations in various livestock populations, such as pigs and cattle; see Pork cycle. However, Rosen et al. (1994) proposed an alternative model which showed that because of the three-year life cycle of beef cattle, cattle populations would fluctuate over time even if ranchers had perfectly rational expectations.
[edit] Human experimental data
In 1989, Wellford conducted twelve experimental sessions each conducted with five participants over thirty periods simulating the stable and unstable case. Her results show that the unstable case did not result in the divergent behavior we see with cobweb expectations but rather the participants converged toward the rational expectations equilibrium. However, the price path variance in the unstable case was greater than that in the stable case (and the difference was shown to be statistically significant).
One way of interpreting these results is to say that in the long run, the participants behaved as if they had rational expectations, but that in the short run they made mistakes. These mistakes caused larger fluctuations in the unstable case than in the stable case.
[edit] References
- W. Nicholson, Microeconomic Theory, 7th ed., Ch. 17, pp. 524-538. Dryden Press: ISBN 0030244749.
- J. Arifovic, 'Genetic Algorithm Learning and the Cobweb Model ', Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, vol. 18, Issue 1, (January 1994), 3-28.
- N. Kaldor, 'A Classificatory Note on the Determination of Equilibrium', Review of Economic Studies, vol I (February, 1934), 122-36.
- M. Nerlove, 'Adaptive Expectations and Cobweb Phenomena', Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. lxxii (1958), 227-40.
- C.P. Wellford, 'A Laboratory Analysis of Price Dynamics and Expectations in the Cobweb Model', Discussion Paper 89-15 (University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ).
- J.F. Muth, 'Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements', Econometrica, vol. 29 (1961), 315-35.
- S. Rosen, K. Murphy, and J. Scheinkman, 'Cattle cycles', Journal of Political Economy, vol. 102 (1994), pp. 468-92.