Abstract labour and concrete labour

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Part of a series on
Marxism
Sociology and Anthropology
Alienation
Bourgeoisie
Class consciousness
Commodity fetishism
Communism
Cultural hegemony
Exploitation
Human nature
Ideology
Proletariat
Reification
Relations of production
Socialism
Economics
Marxian economics
Commodity
Labour power
Law of value
Means of production
Mode of production
Productive forces
Surplus labour
Surplus value
Transformation problem
Wage labour
History
Anarchism and Marxism
Capitalist mode of production
Class struggle
Dictatorship of the proletariat
Primitive accumulation of capital
Proletarian revolution
Proletarian internationalism
World Revolution
Philosophy
Marxist philosophy
Historical materialism
Dialectical materialism
Analytical Marxism
Marxist autonomism
Marxist feminism
Marxist humanism
Structural Marxism
Western Marxism
Young Marx
Important Marxists
Karl Marx
Friedrich Engels
Karl Kautsky
Georgi Plekhanov
Vladimir Lenin
Leon Trotsky
Rosa Luxemburg
Mao Zedong
Georg Lukács
Antonio Gramsci
Karl Korsch
Frankfurt School
Louis Althusser
Che Guevara
Criticisms
Criticisms of Marxism
Full list
Communism Portal
This box: view  talk  edit

Abstract labour and concrete labour refer to a distinction made by Karl Marx in his critique of political economy. This distinction is introduced in chapter 1 of Capital, where Marx writes:

"On the one hand all labour is, speaking physiologically, an expenditure of human labour power, and in its character of identical abstract human labour, it creates and forms the value of commodities. On the other hand, all labour is the expenditure of human labour power in a special form and with a definite aim, and in this, its character of concrete useful labour, it produces use values." [1]

Contents

[edit] Abstract treatment of labour-time

In order to make this distinction, it must be possible to think abstractly about human work, and consider it separately from any particular worker performing it. Only on that basis, it is possible to conceive of quantities of labour (X amount of labour hours, or Y amount of workers).

In statistical reports, for example, reference is made to "the labour force" and quantities of total hours worked are calculated. This is an abstract way of viewing human work, and the workers that perform it. Or, if we take the concept of an output/labour ratio (the ratio of the value of output and the number of hours worked or the number of workers), this is again an abstract way to view labour.

Another example is the concept of unit labour costs, i.e. the cost in labour per product unit, expressible in hours or in money-prices. In time use surveys, a statistical attempt is made to quantify and average out the different types of activities people normally spend their time on.

In official economics, workers do not exist anymore; they are just an abstract "factor of production" or a "labour input" or a "consumer". Workers enter into the analysis only in management theory.

[edit] Abstract labour and exchange

Marx himself considered that all economising reduced to the economical use of human labour-time; "to economise" ultimately meant saving on human energy and effort.

However, according to Marx, the achievement of abstract thinking about human labour, and the ability to quantify it, is closely related to the historical development of economic exchange in general, and more specifically commodity trade.

In fact, he argues the abstraction in thought is the reflex of a real process, in which commercial trade not only alters the way labour is viewed, but also how it is practically treated.

If different products are exchanged in market trade, Marx argues, the exchange process at the same time relates and commensurates the quantities of labour expended to produce those products, regardless of whether the traders are consciously aware of that.

Therefore, the exchange process itself involves the making of a real abstraction, namely abstraction from the particular characteristics of concrete (specific) labour that produced the commodities whose value is equated in trade. Closely related to this, is the growth of a cash economy, and Marx makes the historical observation that:

"In proportion as exchange bursts its local bonds, and the value of commodities more and more expands into an embodiment of human labour in the abstract, in the same proportion the character of money attaches itself to commodities that are by Nature fitted to perform the social function of a universal equivalent. Those commodities are the precious metals." [2]

In a more complex division of labour, it becomes difficult or even impossible to equate the value of all different labour-efforts directly. But money enables us to express and compare the value of all different labour-efforts - more or less accurately - in money-units (initially, quantities of gold, silver, or bronze). This is illustrated by the popular saying, "time is money".

[edit] Abstract labour and capitalism

If the production process itself becomes organised as a specifically capitalist production process, then the abstraction process is deepened, because production labour itself becomes directly treated and organised in terms of its commercial exchange value, and in terms of its capacity to create new value for the buyer of that labour.

Quite simply, in this case, a quantity of labour-time is equal to a quantity of money, and it can be calculated that X hours of labour - regardless of who in particular performs them - create, or are worth, Y amounts of new product value. In this way, labour is practically rendered abstract.

The abstraction is completed when a labour market is established which very exactly quantifies the money-price applying to all kinds of different occupational functions, permitting equations such as:

x amount of qualified labor = y amounts of unskilled labour.

It can also be calculated that it costs a certain amount of time and money to train a worker to perform a certain task, and how much value that adds to the workers'labour.

As a corollary, in these conditions workers will increasingly treat the paid work they do as something distinct or separate from their personality. Work becomes "just work", it no longer necessarily says anything at all about the identity or personality of the worker. With the development of an average skill level in the workforce, the same job can also be done by many different workers, and most workers can do many different jobs; nobody is necessarily tied to one type of work all his life anymore. Thus we can talk of "a job" as an abstract function that could be filled by anybody with the required skills.

[edit] Controversies

Marx regarded the distinction between abstract and concrete labour as being among the most important innovations he contributed to the theory of economic value, and subsequently Marxian scholars have debated a great deal about its theoretical significance.

For some, abstract labour is an economic category which applies only to the capitalist mode of production, i.e. it applies only, when human labour power or work-capacity is universally treated as a commodity with a certain monetary cost or earnings potential.

Others however argue that the abstract treatment of human labour-time is something that evolved and developed in the course of the whole history of trade, or even precedes it, to the extent that primitive agriculture already involves attempts to economise labour, by calculating the comparative quantities of labour-time involved in producing different kinds of outputs.

In that case, the equation of different quantities of labour-time through economic exchange is not a necessary prerequisite for the abstract treatment of labour-time; all that is required is that different labour-efforts in society are comparable, yielding averages indicating the "normal" labour-time associated with a task.

What a cash economy then adds, is a much more refined and sophisticated quantification of amounts of society's labour-time, expressed in money-prices - a further development of the abstraction of labour which, however, was already occurring prior to the advent of capitalist industry.

Thus, on this view, capitalism universalizes the abstract treatment of labour-time, clearly separating paid work from other activities; through the universal use of money, all forms of labour become comparable in value, and can be economised on that basis. But this economising occurs in a specific pattern: its capitalistic purpose is to maximise the yield of surplus value to private owners of capital.

[edit] References

  • Karl Marx, Das Kapital.
  • Isaac I. Rubin, Essays in Marx's Theory of Value.
  • Harry Braverman, Labor and Monopoly Capital.
  • Roman Rosdolsky, The Making of Marx's 'Capital'.
  • Kozo Uno, Principles of Political Economy.
  • Makoto Itoh, The Basic Theory of Capitalism.
  • Ulrich Krause, Abstract Labour and Money. In H.D. Kurz, N. Salvadori (eds.): The Elgar Companion to Classical Economics, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham UK, 1998, 6-10.
  • Ulrich Krause, Money and Abstract Labour : On the Analytical Foundations of Political Economy. Translated by Peter Burgess. Edited by Jon Rothschild. Verso.

[edit] See also

In other languages