Talk:Kelly criterion

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

The formula can be simplified:

(bp-q)/b => b(p-q/b)/b => q=1-p so k=p-(1-p)/b

--Geremy78 09:49, 28 January 2006 (UTC)

Contents

[edit] Generalized Kelly Strategy

The "generalized form of the formula" given in the article isn't really the most general. The most general expression of the Kelly criterion is to find the fraction f of the bankroll that maximizes the expectation of the logarithm of the results. For simple bets with two outcomes, one of which involves losing the entire amount bet, the formula given in the article is correct and is easily derived from the general form. For bets with many possible outcomes (such as betting on the stock market), the calculation is naturally more complicated.

One statement in the article,

In addition to maximizing the long-run growth rate, the formula has the added benefit of having zero risk of ruin, as the formula will never allow 100% of the bankroll to be wagered on any gamble having less than 100% chance of winning.

isn't strictly true from a theoretical standpoint. It is always true that Kelly strategy has zero risk of ruin, but in the general case it is not true that a bet of 100% of the bankroll is not allowed. If the probability of losing the entire amount of the bet is zero, then bets of 100% and even larger (buying stocks on margin, for example) are allowed. Investing in a stock index (as opposed to a single stock or small number of stocks) could allow such percentages, if we assume the index can never go broke (even though individual stocks might), and that the index has a positive expectation of outcome (adjusted for inflation, since we are dealing with money invested over time). Of course, any real-world investment will have a non-zero chance of going bust, and therefore Kelly strategy will indicate a bet of less than 100% of bankroll.

Rsmoore 07:55, 4 February 2006 (UTC)

[edit] Formula presentation

While the Kelly Criterion formula can be "simplified" to remove the q term, it actually becomes longer, less intuitive, and harder to remember. As a result, it is generally presented as (bp-q)/b.

Whoever "corrected" the formula to (bp-1)/(b-1), this is incorrect. I have changed it back to the correct formula. I cite as my source William Poundstone's book Fortune's Formula: The Untold Story of the Scientific Betting System That Beat the Casinos and Wall Street. Additional sources can also probably be found all over the internet.

[edit] Added disadvantages section

The information in that section is all from reading Poundstone's book. The book is very very verbose and completely non-mathematical - designed for bedtime reading I expect. It could have been condensced to 1/10th. of the length without losing much. I have seen more concise explainations of Kelly in other popular books about chance, although I do not remember reading before about the volatility problem or over-betting. Something only mentioned in one sentance is that its easy to overestimate the true odds and unconciously overbet, leading to ruin. It is suggested this happened to Long Term Capital Management.

There are no explainations of the maths behind the information stated in the book - you have to take it on trust. For those with busy lives you can find all the relevant info by looking up Kelly criterion and geometric average in the index. The pages in the 2005 hardback edition I thought were most relevant were pgs. 73, 191, 194-201,229,231,232, 297, 298.

It does have an extensive bibliography, and there is a reference for: Bernoulli, Daniel (1954) "Exposition of a New Theory on the Measurement of Risk" Trans. Louise Sommer, Econometrica 22:23-36. Wonder if its available online? Henry A Latane/ did some academic papers about the geometric mean criterion. The books (academic or popular) of William T Ziemba also seem of interest, including Beat the Racetrack.

Poundstone describes the Kelly criterion in his own way (pg.73): he says you should gamble the fraction edge/odds of your bankroll. Edge is how much you expect to win on average. Odds are the public or 'tote-board' odds. Example: the tote board odds for a horse are 5 to 1. You think the horse has a 1 in 3 chance of winning. So by betting on the horse you on average get $200 back for a $100 stake, giving a net profit of $100. The edge is the $100 profit divided by the $100 stake, giving 1. So in this case the edge is 1. The odds are 5 to 1 - you only need the 5. So edge/odds is 1/5 - you should bet one fifth of your bankroll.

As someone who has never gambled on races, I find "odds" confusing. I wish someone would also provide a formula in the article where only p is used, that is more suitable for use with investments.

Where the book really falls down is in describing multiple bets. Poundstone just baldly says you can bet more of your bankroll with simultaneous bets - but he dosnt give any how or why, although this would be useful to know. Perhaps he doesnt understand this himself.

As someone who is currently making heavily geared real-estate investments, I think the encyc. article should go into much more detail than currently, including practical applications. I wish I had some guidance on how much I should optimally invest. I find the idea of choosing the greatest geometric mean much easier to understand than the Kelly criterion. In business investments I suppose you would take the geometric mean of the expected net present values - or would you?

As Poundstone points out (I think), the geometric average rule does have a flaw. For example, if you had a bet for a $10 stake where you had a 99% chance of winning $1000000 and a 1% chance of winning $0, then the geometric mean criteria would tell you to ignore this bet completely! (Please tell me if I've got this wrong.)

The book is about 90% chat about financial things only tenuously linked to Kellys criteria - about various imprisoned and/or ruined Wall St. multi-millionaires, about the links one large well known entertainment company is said to have/had with the Mafia. It says nothing about Shannon's communication theory, and zilch about the links between this and Kelly's criterion, which was my reason for ordering the book. It does describe Thorp quite a lot though.

Perhaps someone could add some references to some more concise popular expositions of the criterion.

[edit] Shannons stock system

Continuing from the above, Poundstones book also mentions an interesting (theorectical) investment system devised by Shannon.

Shannons actual stock investments (the book says) were buy and hold. He selected stocks by extrapolating earnings growth (using human judgement). Two or three of Shannons stocks accounted for nearly all the value of his portfolio.

He also devised an interesting theorectical system for investing in stock with a lot of volatility but no trend (pg. 202). Put half your capital into stock and half into cash. Each day rebalance by shifting from stock to cash or vice versa to keep these proportions. Surprisingly, the total value grows. In practice the dealing commissions would remove any profit.

This system is now known as a "constant-proprtion rebalanced portfolio", and has been studied by economists Mark Rubenstein, Eugene Fama, and Thomas Cover.