Child labor

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

The labour movement series
Child labor
Comparisons
Eight-hour day
Labour in economics
Labour history (discipline)
Labour law
Labour rights
Proletariat
Issues & events timeline
Trade union
Strike
General strike
List of strikes
Syndicalism
Social Movement Unionism
Worldwide:
Unions by country
List of trade unions
Edit this template

Child labor (or child labour) is the employment of children under an age determined by law or custom. This practice is considered exploitative by many countries and international organizations. Child labor was not seen as a problem throughout most of history, only becoming a disputed issue with the beginning of universal schooling and the concepts of laborers and children's rights.

Child labor can include factory work, mining or quarrying, agriculture, helping in the parents' business, having one's own small business (for example selling food), or doing odd jobs. Some children work as guides for tourists, sometimes combined with bringing in business for shops and restaurants (where they may also work as waiters). However, rather than in factories and sweatshops, most non-agriculture child labor occurs in the informal sector, "selling on the street, at work in agriculture or hidden away in houses — far from the reach of official labour inspectors and from media scrutiny." [1]

The most controversial forms of work include the military use of children as well as child prostitution. Less controversial, and often legal with some restrictions, are work as child actors and child singers, as well as agricultural work outside of the school year (seasonal work).

Contents

[edit] Human rights

The United Nations and the International Labour Organization consider child labor exploitative, [2] [3] with the UN stipulating, in article 32 of the Convention on the Rights of the Child that:

...States Parties recognize the right of the child to be protected from economic exploitation and from performing any work that is likely to be hazardous or to interfere with the child's education, or to be harmful to the child's health or physical, mental, spiritual, moral or social development.[3]

In many countries,[4] it is considered inappropriate or exploitative if a child below a certain age works, excluding household chores or schoolwork. An employer is often not allowed to hire a child below a certain age. This minimum age depends on the country; in the United States, the minimum age to work in an establishment without parents' consent and restrictions is age 16.[5] Based on this understanding of the use of children as laborers, it is now considered by wealthy countries to be a human rights violation, and is outlawed, while some poorer countries may allow or tolerate it.

Poor families often rely on the labors of their children for survival and sometimes it is their only source of income. This type of work is often hidden away because it is not in the industrial sector. Child labor is employed in subsistence agriculture, in the household, or in the urban informal sector. A related problem is that people are often more preoccupied with the long-term survival and well being of their families than with their own direct, short-term interests. Child labor prohibition has to address the dual challenge of providing children with both short-term income and long-term prospects. Some youth rights groups, however, feel that prohibiting work below a certain age violates human rights, reducing children's options and leaving them subject to the whims of those with money. The reasons a child would consent to do such work may vary greatly. An example of this consent to work would be if a child says he or she wants to work, perhaps because the earnings are attractive or if the child hates school, because such consent may not necessarily be informed consent. However, the workplace may still be an undesirable situation for a child or adult in the long run.

The United States also has extensive child labor laws. In the 1990s every country in the world except for Somalia and the United States became a signatory to the Convention on the Rights of the Child, or CRC. The CRC provides the strongest, most consistent international legal language prohibiting illegal child labor.

[edit] Industrial Revolution

Child laborer, Newberry, South Carolina, 1908
Enlarge
Child laborer, Newberry, South Carolina, 1908

In the West, during the Industrial Revolution, use of child labour was commonplace, often in factories, but on the decline. In England and Scotland in 1788, about two-thirds of the workers in the new water-powered textile factories were children [1]. Subsequently, largely due to the campaigning of Lord Shaftesbury, a series of Factory Acts were passed to restrict gradually the hours that children were allowed to work, and to improve safety. Marx argued that the industrial revolution increased hardship for children.[6] Historian E. P. Thompson notes in The Making of the English Working Class that child labor was not new, and had been "an intrinsic part of the agricultural and industrial economy before 1780"; however he argues that "there was a drastic increase in the intensity of exploitation of child labour between 1780 and 1840, and every historian acquainted with the sources knows this is so. This was true in the mines, both in inefficient small-scale pits where the roadways were sometimes so narrow that children could not easily pass through them; where - as the coal face drew further away from the shaft - children were in demand as 'hurreyers' and to operate the ventilation ports. In the mills, the child and juvenile labour force grew yearly; and in several of the out-worker or 'dishonourable' trades the hours of labour became longer and work more intense."[5]

Other historians have disagreed with this verdict. Objectivist economic historian Robert Hessen says

"claims of increased misery...[are] based on ignorance of how squalid life actually had been earlier. Before children began earning money working in factories, they had been sent to live in parish poorhouses, apprenticed as unpaid household servants, rented out for backbreaking agricultural labor, or became beggars, vagrants, thieves, and prostitutes (Nutten). The precapitalist "good old days" simply never existed" [7]
"The pre-factory age was not a time of happy, contented kids. From 1730 to 1740, 75 percent of children in England died before age five. From 1810 to 1829, supposedly the evil age of the factory, infant mortality fell to 32 percent and would continue to drop. Capitalism and the industrial revolution gave youngsters a chance to survive. " [8]

Laws were passed to prohibit child labor in the industrialized countries; however it is unclear whether this legislation is the principal cause of the decline in levels of juvenile employment.[9] Research by Clark Nardinelli suggests that child labor was already decreasing in the United States and Western Europe prior to the passage of legislation, due to an increasing demand for educated and literate adults brought about by an increasing technological sophistication of industry. The demand for educated workers also provided an incentive for children to stay in school to meet the new demands of industry.[9] Nonetheless, neoclassical economists such as Nardinelli have also been ridiculed for suggesting that children essentially volunteered to be exploited, submitting, for example, to whippings out of a kind of entrepreneurial initiative.[10]

[edit] Boycotts

Two girls wearing banners with slogan "ABOLISH CHILD SLAVERY!!" in English and Yiddish. Probably taken during May 1, 1909 labor parade in New York City.
Enlarge
Two girls wearing banners with slogan "ABOLISH CHILD SLAVERY!!" in English and Yiddish. Probably taken during May 1, 1909 labor parade in New York City.

Concern has been raised about the buying public's moral complicity in buying products assembled or otherwise manufactured in developing countries with child labor. However, boycotting products manufactured through child labor may force these children to turn to more dangerous or strenuous professions due to necessity, such as prostitution or agriculture.

For example, a UNICEF study found that that 5,000 to 7,000 Nepalese children turned to prostitution after the United States banned that country's carpet exports in the 1990s. Also, after the Child Labor Deterrence Act was introduced in the US, an estimated 50,000 children were dismissed from their garment industry jobs in Bangladesh, leaving many to resort to jobs such as "stone-crushing, street hustling, and prostitution," --"all of them more hazardous and exploitative than garment production" according to a UNICEF study [2]. The study says that boycotts are "blunt instruments with long-term consequences, that can actually harm rather than help the children involved."

[edit] Defense of child labour

Child laborer, New Jersey, 1910. Click image for more background on the specific child.
Enlarge
Child laborer, New Jersey, 1910. Click image for more background on the specific child.

Children's participation in economic activity was commonplace prior to the Industrial Revolution as children performed labor on their farms or for their families. Milton Friedman claimed that the Industrial Revolution saw a net decline in child labor, rather than an increase.[11] According to this theory, for which Friedman cited no sources, children began to work in factories, but greater numbers of children stopped working in agriculture. While accepting this overall child labor declined in this period, other commentators draw a qualitative distinction between domestic work and participation in the wider (waged) labor-market.[5] The usefulness of the experience of the industrial revolution in making predictions about current trends has been disputed. Economic historian Hugh Cunningham notes that:

"Fifty years ago it might have been assumed that, just as child labour had declined in the developed world in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, so it would also, in a trickle-down fashion, in the rest of the world. Its failure to do that, and its re-emergence in the developed world, raise questions about its role in any economy, whether national or global." [12]

Friedman believed that the absence of child labor is a luxury that many poor states cannot yet afford. To prohibit it is to prevent the economic growth necessary to relieve a society of the need for child labor. In poor societies these children will be put to work by their families by whatever means because they cannot afford to feed idle and unproductive children. Moreover, in addition to possibly increasing family costs on a depleted family income, parents may have to forego potential labor time and income, to care for idle children.[11] Some argue that if industrial child labor is legally forbidden, then many children are relegated to working in more dangerous black market occupations such as prostitution.[13]

[edit] References

  1. ^ The State of the World's Children 1997. UNICEF. Retrieved on 2006-10-05.
  2. ^ Worst Forms of Child Labour Recommendation, 1999. International Labour Organization. Retrieved on 2006-10-05.
  3. ^ a b Convention on the Rights of the Child. United Nations. Retrieved on 2006-10-05.
  4. ^ Ratification of the Convention on the Rights of the Child. Office of the United Nations High Commissioner for Human Rights. Retrieved on 2006-10-05.
  5. ^ a b c E. P. Thompson, The Making of the English Working Class, (Penguin, 1968), pp. 366-7
  6. ^ Marx. Karl. Capital. vol. I. Chicago: Charles H. Kerr & Company, 1909
  7. ^ Hessen, Robert, Capitalism, Concise Encyclopedia of Economics
  8. ^ Anderson, William (1996). Kathie Lee's Children. Free Market, Volume 14, Number 9. Retrieved on 2006-11-01.
  9. ^ a b Nardinelli, Clark, Child Labor and the Industrial Revolution (Indiana University Press, 1990)
  10. ^ Michael Perelman, The Perverse Economy: The Impact of Markets on People and the Environment (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2003). pp 153-154
  11. ^ a b Friedman,Milton. Take it to the Limits: Milton Friedman on Libertarianism." Interview. February 10,1999.<http://www.uncommonknowledge.org/99winter/324.html#top>
  12. ^ Hugh Cunninghame, "The decline of child labour: labour markets and family economies in Europe and North America since 1830", Economic History Review, 2000.
  13. ^ DeGregori, Thomas R., "Child Labor or Child Prostitution?" Cato Institute. http://www.cato.org/dailys/10-08-02.html

hi

[edit] See also

International conventions and other instruments:

Types of programmes focussing on child labour

Country-specific programmes:

[edit] External links